The political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries

Thanh Cong Nguyen (Faculty of Economics and Business, Phenikaa University, Hanoi, Vietnam)
Thi Linh Tran (Faculty of Economics and Business, Phenikaa University, Hanoi, Vietnam)

Journal of Economics and Development

ISSN: 1859-0020

Article publication date: 22 June 2023

Issue publication date: 16 August 2023

1138

Abstract

Purpose

This paper examines the political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries using a sample of 91 countries from 1992 to 2019.

Design/methodology/approach

This paper employs a pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) model with clustered standard errors at the country level. To address endogeneity issues, the authors also employ a two-step system generalized methods of moments model.

Findings

The authors find clear evidence of political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries. The authors consistently find that incumbents increase total government spending, particularly in economic affairs, public services and social welfare, in the year before an election and the election year. In contrast, they contract spending in the year after an election.

Research limitations/implications

Policymakers should be aware of the political budget cycles during election years. Promoting control of corruption and democracy helps to alleviate the effects of the political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries.

Originality/value

The authors are among the first to explore the political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries by focusing on the total government spending and its main compositions, including expenditures on economic affairs, public services and social welfare. Besides, the authors also explore the conditioning effects of control of corruption, political ideology and democracy.

Keywords

Citation

Nguyen, T.C. and Tran, T.L. (2023), "The political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries", Journal of Economics and Development, Vol. 25 No. 3, pp. 205-225. https://doi.org/10.1108/JED-01-2023-0015

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, Thanh Cong Nguyen and Thi Linh Tran

License

Published in the Journal of Economics and Development. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) license. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this license may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

The political budget cycle theory suggests that incumbent chief executives and governments act opportunistically before elections to improve the chance of re-election (Nordhaus, 1975; Alesina et al., 1997). Increasing government spending serves as a positive signal of incumbents' “competence,” which refers to their ability to provide more public goods before elections (Rogoff, 1990). They can increase capital spending to generate short-term economic growth (Klein and Sakurai, 2015; Bonfatti and Forni, 2019) and/or expand spending on social welfare to improve the situation of low- and middle-income voters being left behind (Vergne, 2009; Schneider, 2010). However, spending more on social welfare, such as health, education and social protections, to placate voters might not produce the same rewards for incumbents as different constituencies' interests often compete (Barberia et al., 2011). For example, increasing the benefits of social insurance and pensions may not benefit a large share of low- and middle-income voters in emerging and developing countries as they work in the informal sector.

For this reason, to increase the chance of re-election, incumbents could rely more on investment infrastructure – especially on projects with high immediate visibility – to signal their competence to electorates. As voters cannot perfectly observe government expenses and the level of the budget deficit, they tend to rely on observed information about government spending before an election to make inferences about the persistence of incumbents' competence over time (Shi and Svensson, 2006). Increasing spending on social welfare and investment infrastructure tends to happen in the year preceding elections as it takes time for those policies to have real effects on the economy (Barberia et al., 2011).

Some studies challenge the political budget cycle by pointing out that voters are aware of the opportunistic behavior of incumbents and do not respond to manipulated fiscal policies before an election (see, for example, Peltzman, 1992; Brender and Drazen, 2008). In this regard, another strand of the literature provides evidence that incumbents generate electoral benefits without being punished by voters by changing the compositions of government spending rather than overall spending (see, for example, Drazen and Eslava, 2010; Schneider, 2010).

However, the existing theoretical models and empirical evidence on the political budget theory tend to focus on developed countries such as Italy (Bonfatti and Forni, 2019), Portugal (Veiga and Veiga, 2007; Castro and Martins, 2013), Germany (Foremny and Riedel, 2014), among others. Significantly absent from this literature is whether and how the political budget cycle theory applies to emerging and developing countries. Particular attention should be focused on emerging and developing countries as voters lack the necessary information to assess economic policy and incumbents' performance, leaving the ground for opportunistic behavior to thrive (Vergne, 2009). Moreover, the tax base tends to be low in those countries, which prevents incumbents from reducing taxes for political support. Thus, incumbents in emerging and developing countries prioritize public spending over tax reduction to enhance political support (Schuknecht, 2000). Therefore, to fill this gap in the literature, this paper revisits the theory of the political budget cycle in the context of emerging and developing countries.

Using a panel of 91 emerging and developing countries from 1992 to 2019, we consistently find that election years and the year before an election witness an increase in government spending, while government spending declines in the year after an election. These findings confirm the existence of the political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries. In particular, incumbent governments expand public spending before and during an election to create short-run economic growth for electoral advantages. Then, they reduce spending after an election to correct imbalances generated before elections. We find that the increase in government spending is more pronounced in the year before an election than in election years. One explanation is that incumbent governments may account for the time lag as fiscal expansion policies take time to affect the economy.

Digging deeper into the compositions of government expenditure, we find that incumbents generate nomination benefits by increasing spending on economic affairs, public services and social welfare. Spending on economic affairs appears to be stronger than that on other dimensions because incumbent governments favor spending on economic-related projects with high immediate visibility to attract voters. Our additional analyses also provide evidence that opportunistic behavior is less pronounced in countries with higher levels of control of corruption.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews related literature on the political budget cycle. Section 3 describes our variables and the research model. Section 4 presents our empirical findings and some additional analyses. Section 5 addresses endogeneity concerns. Section 6 concludes.

2. Literature review

2.1 Theory and related literature

The existing literature on the political cycle has offered both theoretical frameworks and empirical evidence that economic conditions determine the success of an election. In this regard, favorable economic conditions are associated with a higher probability of incumbents being re-elected (Castro and Martins, 2019). In sharp contrast, voters punish their incumbents for poor economic conditions by voting for their opposition candidates and political parties (Lindvall, 2014; Nguyen et al., 2020). Thus, incumbents tend to stimulate short-term economic growth before elections to increase their re-election probabilities.

The classic political budget cycle theory suggests that politicians act opportunistically before elections by distorting fiscal policies to maximize their re-election prospects (Nordhaus, 1975; Rogoff, 1990; Nguyen et al., 2020). In particular, they tend to increase public spending on highly visible infrastructure to electorates, such as bridges and rural roads, to signal their competence (Rogoff, 1990; Veiga and Veiga, 2007; Lewis, 2018). Increasing government spending on economic affairs before elections helps to stimulate demand and boost economic growth, especially during periods of economic recessions (see, for example, Devarajan et al., 1996; Parui, 2021). Besides, short-term opportunistic effects can also be observed in the social sector, where incumbents increase spending on the welfare state to placate citizens, especially low-income voters (Schneider, 2010). Similarly, Nguyen et al. (2022a) examined social spending in 108 countries from 1991 to 2019 and found that governments increase social spending (health, education and social protection) as a percentage of GDP by around 0.14% during the election years. Based on these arguments, we posit the following hypothesis.

H1a.

Incumbent governments increase spending before an election

However, prior studies also provide conflicting views regarding the opportunistic behavior of incumbents. Brender and Drazen (2008) do not find evidence of higher government spending or budget deficit before elections. Instead, they find that improving budget balance during pre-election periods sends a positive signal to the public as voters are “fiscally conservative” and could punish incumbents that pursue loose fiscal policies before elections. Peltzman (1992) and Alesina et al. (1998) also provide evidence that higher deficits over the term of office lower the probabilities of re-election in developed countries. Considering the change in overall government spending during election periods in 19 developed Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries over the years 1972–1999, Katsimi and Sarantides (2012) also find no clear evidence of the existence of the political budget cycles.

Another strand of the literature pinpoints the existence of incumbents' opportunistic behavior in election years but provides evidence that electoral cycles do not significantly alter overall government spending. One of the possible reasons is that incumbents manipulate fiscal expenditures by changing the compositions of government spending rather than overall spending (Veiga and Veiga, 2007; Schneider, 2010). For example, examining elections in Colombian municipalities, Drazen and Eslava (2010) found that incumbents cut spending on interest payments, transfers to retirees and payments to temporary worker contracts and significantly expanded spending on infrastructures such as road construction and water plans before elections. Klein and Sakurai (2015) tell a similar story, in which politicians in Brazil tend to shift current spending to capital spending while budget balances and overall expenditure remain unchanged. Similar evidence exists in Italian municipal elections (Bonfatti and Forni, 2019). Thus, given that voters might be rational and punish incumbents for running large deficits (Drazen and Eslava, 2010), by changing the compositions of government spending, incumbents can benefit from the opportunistic fiscal cycle before elections while keeping a controlled fiscal balance. Thus, we formulate the following hypothesis.

H1b.

Election cycles do not have a significant impact on the total government spending

The political budget cycle theory also indicates that governments are compelled to contract government spending to correct unbalances generated by opportunistic behavior before elections (Rogoff, 1990; Nordhaus, 1975; Castro and Martins, 2019). This sheds light on Block (2001), who finds that government spending two years after a competitive election is lower than that in the year before an election in developing countries. Results are similar to Ames (1977), who concludes that government spending in Latin American countries increased by 6.3% before elections and reduced by more than 7.6% in post-election years from 1947 to 1982. The author argues that governments contracted capital spending after elections as they had generated imbalances before the polls. This evidence leads us to the following research hypothesis.

H2.

Government spending is lower in the year after an election

3. Data, variables and methods

3.1 Data

Our sample consists of 1,441 country-year observations representing 91 countries from 1992 to 2019. The list of countries is reported in Table A1 in Appendix. All country-level variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles to lower the influence of outliers. Our explanatory variables show remarkably little correlations (see Table A2 in Appendix). The correlation coefficients of electoral variables with control variables are smaller than |0.31|, alleviating the concern that multicollinearity problems drive our main findings.

Details of all variables used in this study and their data sources are presented in Table 1. Their descriptive statistics are provided in Table 2 [1]. On average, the level of government expenditure in our sample is 25.93% of GDP. Spending on social welfare (including health, education and social protections) makes up the largest share of government expenditure to GDP, at 10.98%. As mentioned earlier, we only focus on the three most important dimensions of government spending, including economic affairs, public services and social welfare, which accounts for more than 22% of government spending on GDP in total. Spending on other dimensions, such as defense, environmental protection, recreation, culture and religion and housing and community amenities, only contributes less than 4% of spending on GDP, for which we do not account in this study. Throughout this paper, we assume that government spending is not affected by the level of central bank independence. In fact, central bank independence can weaken the incentives of incumbents in expanding fiscal policies (Aklin and Kern, 2021). For example, a proactive central bank can increase interest rates to offset the effects of increased government spending. To test the validity of our assumption, we employ the central bank independence index by Garriga (2016) as a control variable. We find that our main findings remain consistent [2]. However, we do not control for central bank independence in this paper as this limits our sample to the year 2012 and significantly reduces the number of observations (more than 33.6%) due to data constraints.

3.2 The election cycle and control variables

We source data for executive elections from the World Bank's Political Institutions Database. To provide a comprehensive view of government spending during election periods, we introduce three electoral dummy variables to capture government spending in the year before an election (Pre-election), election year (Election) and the year after an election (Post-election). The classic political budget cycle theory suggests that government spending increases before an election and reduces after the election.

In addition to the above independent variables of interest, we also control for factors found in the literature to impact government spending significantly. Regarding demographic characteristics, population growth (Population growth) is included as it is associated with a greater burden on the government budget (Holcombe and Williams, 2008; Nguyen et al., 2021). Median age (Median age) is also considered because an aging population is associated with higher demand for social welfare (McManus, 2019; Nguyen et al., 2022a). Similarly, we account for the unemployment rate (Unemployment rate) because governments have to increase spending on social protections at higher levels of unemployment.

Regarding macroeconomic controllers, we also include GDP growth (GDP growth) to account for the business cycle (Nguyen, 2021a). Moreover, higher inflation (Inflation) discourages governments from spending as it exacerbates inflation problems (Brender and Drazen, 2013). Government debt (Government debt) is a greater debt burden that could prevent a government from increasing total expenditure. Tax revenue (Tax revenue) constitutes another control variable as tax revenue is the fundamental source of government expenditure.

3.3 Methods

To examine the effects of the election cycle on government spending, we employ the following research model:

(1)Expenditurei,t=βElectionsi,t+δControllersi,t1+α+τt+εi,t,
where i and t are country and year, respectively. Expenditure is the ratio of government expenditure to GDP; Elections represents electoral variables (Pre-election, Election or Post-election); Controllers is the vector of control variables; α is the constant term; τt captures time (year) fixed effects and εit is the usual error term. Control variables enter lagged one year to alleviate simultaneous and endogeneity issues. As elections vary between countries, we cluster standard errors at the country level throughout this paper. Despite controlling for a range of control variables found in the literature to have an important impact on government spending, our main findings might be driven by omitted variables. To check for the sensitivity of our findings, we also use two-way clustering standard errors at both country and year levels and control for country-fixed effects, a point to which we return later in Section 4.8. Besides, we also employ a two-step system generalized methods of moments (GMM) model in Section 5 to alleviate endogeneity concerns.

4. Results and discussions

This section examines the effects of the election cycle (Pre-election, Election and Post-election) on total government spending. Then we delve into the main compositions of government spending, including economic affairs, public services and social welfare. Then we explore the conditioning effects of control of corruption on the relationship between the election cycle and government spending. Finally, we use different clusters of standard errors to check for the sensitivity of our findings.

4.1 The election cycle and government spending

Table 3 reports our baseline results on the effects of the election cycle on government spending using a pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) model. Turning to the main novelty of this study, the hypothesis that incumbents increase government spending before elections (Hypothesis H1a) receives clear empirical support [3]. In particular, the coefficient on Pre-election is positive and statistically significant (at more than 99% confidence level), indicating that incumbent governments appear to increase government expenditure one year ahead of an election. Economically, the year before an election is associated with a 1.75% increase in government spending over GDP, ceteris paribus. The finding is consistent with the classic political budget cycle theory (Nordhaus, 1975; Rogoff, 1990) and well-established empirical findings provided in the literature (see, for example, Veiga and Veiga, 2007; Lewis, 2018). Generally speaking, incumbents in emerging and developing countries expand fiscal policies before an election to increase their chance of re-election.

Similarly, the coefficient on Election in Column 2 shows that incumbent governments also increase government spending during election years, further supporting the political budget cycle theory. However, the magnitude of this effect is smaller than that of Pre-election, indicating that governments have more incentive to employ fiscal policy expansion for political purposes in the year before an election. This is not surprising as the effect time lag implies that when fiscal policy is enacted, it takes time for the policy to affect the economy. Thus, incumbent governments may significantly increase spending in the year before an election to account for the effect of time lag and allow voters to recognize the impact of their policies on the economy during the election year.

The political budget cycle theory also implies that governments tend to lower their expenditure after an election to correct unbalances generated before the election (Castro and Martins, 2019). Indeed, Post-election is found to have a negative and statistically significant impact on government spending, confirming that governments contract spending after an election. This evidence confirms that political budget cycles exist in emerging and developing countries.

Our control variables provide some further results that are worth highlighting. In line with our conjectures, higher population growth, median age and unemployment rate are associated with higher government spending. A larger debt burden and higher inflation are found to reduce government spending. Not surprisingly, higher tax revenue, which is the primary source of the government budget, enables governments to spend more.

Our analyses do not confine to overall government spending to provide a complete picture of the election cycle and government spending. Instead, we dig deeper into the main compositions of government spending, which include spending on economic affairs, public services and social welfare.

4.2 The election cycle and government spending on economic affairs

Table 4 shows the election cycle's impact on government spending on economic affairs. We find that incumbent governments significantly increase spending on economic affairs in the pre-election and election years, agreeing with those reported that incumbents tend to expand capital spending before elections for electoral advantages (see, for example, Ames, 1977; Klein and Sakurai, 2015; Bonfatti and Forni, 2019). In line with the finding of the baseline model, the coefficient on Election is smaller than that of Pre-election, suggesting that policy time lags induce incumbent governments to expand spending on economic affairs one year ahead of an election.

Compared to spending on public services and social welfare, a point to which we return in the next subsections, spending on economic affairs appears more important than other sectors. The finding is in line with Shi and Svensson (2006), who suggest that incumbent governments favor spending on economic affairs, particularly public projects with high immediate visibility, such as infrastructure construction, to make inferences about their persistent competence.

Concerning the year after an election, Post_election is negatively correlated with spending on economic affairs, suggesting that incumbents reduce spending on economic affairs after an election. This is not surprising as the political budget cycle theory suggests that incumbents should cut public spending after elections to correct imbalances generated by increasing spending before elections (Castro and Martins, 2019).

4.3 Electoral cycle and spending on public services

Table 5 presents the findings on the election cycle's impact on government spending on public services. We continue to find that government spending increases before and during an election. Again, spending in election years is smaller than that of the year before, confirming that incumbent governments favor spending in the year before an election to generate electoral advantages. Nevertheless, spending on public services is less pronounced than spending on economic affairs. One explanation is that the main component of spending on public services is public debt transactions, which are periodic and less affected by the political cycle. Besides, we do not find evidence that governments contract spending on public services after an election.

4.4 Electoral cycle and spending on social welfare

Social spending accounts for the largest share of the total government spending. Table 6 displays the election cycle's impact on spending on social welfare, which is measured as the percentage of spending on health, education and social protection to GDP. Pre-election enters positive and statistically significant, indicating that governments expand spending on social welfare before elections. The result aligns with the political budget cycle theory, which suggests that governments should increase social spending before an election to placate voters, especially low-income ones (Vergne, 2009; Nguyen et al., 2022a). Election appears to increase government spending on social welfare in election years, but its effect is greater than the year before an election. We suggest that spending on social welfare, such as social protections, does not involve policy time lag as in the case of spending on economic affairs since they immediately increase people's disposable income. Thus, governments may favor spending of social expenditure in election years rather than the year before an election. It is similar to spending on economic affairs, where governments reduce social spending in the aftermath of an election to correct imbalances generated before and during election years (Castro and Martins, 2019).

Overall, in line with the political budget cycle theory, our findings provide empirical evidence that government spending increases in the year before an election and in election years, while it reduces in the year after an election. Our findings, however, contrast with some claims that incumbents tend to keep the overall spending stable while generating opportunistic benefits during pre-election periods by changing the allocations of their expenditure (Veiga and Veiga, 2007; Schneider, 2010). One possible reason is that running higher deficits due to the expansion of government spending before an election for electoral advantages could send a negative signal to voters (Schneider, 2010; Klein and Sakurai, 2015; Bonfatti and Forni, 2019). Nevertheless, this relies on the assumption that voters are fully aware of the opportunistic behavior of incumbent governments, which might be possible in some advanced countries. Our sample focuses solely on emerging and developing countries, many of which are new democracies. For this reason, voters – who cannot perfectly observe government expenses and the level of the budget deficit – could assess incumbent governments based on their ability to provide more public goods before elections (Rogoff, 1990).

4.5 The role of control of corruption

Decisions on government spending result from decision-making by politicians who could be motivated mainly by their self-interests. Corrupt politicians may be incentivized to increase government spending to exact large bribes (Mauro, 1998; Vukovic, 2020). However, increasing government expenditure during pre-election and election periods is sensitive as the mainstream political party/leader with the aim to replace the corrupt incumbents could investigate the incumbents' decisions on large expenditures. For example, Pierskalla and Sacks (2018) argue that incumbents may be less incentivized to engage in large government-funded projects and services that can expose them to a politically motivated corruption investigation before and especially during an election. In sharp contrast, some studies suggest that corrupt politicians might not be punished at elections as they can design a system that protects both their rent-seeking behavior and the probability of re-election (Coviello and Gagliarducci, 2017; Vukovic, 2020). Despite ambiguities remaining, little attention has been given to the impact of control of corruption on government spending in times of election. By interacting electoral variables with the level of control of corruption, Table 7 presents the conditioning effects of control of corruption (Corruption control) on the relationships between electoral variables and government spending.

Results presented in Table 7 confirm the existence of a strong, positive, statistically significant and robust relationship between election years and government spending. We find negative and significant coefficients of the interaction terms of Pre-election and Election with Corruption Control, implying that the positive impact of Pre-election and Election on government spending is weakened in countries that better control corruption issues. One explanation is that better control of corruption could prevent corrupt politicians from exploiting the government budget for private benefits before elections. The argument is supported by Coviello and Gagliarducci (2017) and Vukovic (2020) who argue that corrupt governments spend more before elections as they are less likely to be punished at elections as they can design a system that protects both their rent-seeking behavior.

Our findings confirm the role of control of corruption in alleviating the effects of political budget cycles during election years in emerging and developing countries. Although the impact of Post-election on overall government spending remains consistent and significant, the coefficient on interaction term of Post-election with Corruption Control failed to develop a significant coefficient.

4.6 The role of political ideology

Incumbent governments are heterogeneous as they can pursue opposite economic and social policy orientations. Left-wing governments representing the interest of the middle and lower-class constituents tend to favor a more generous welfare state and lower unemployment (McManus, 2019). They also pursue higher government spending and taxes (Hibbs, 1977; Nguyen et al., 2022b). By contrast, right-wing governments drawing support from middle- and upper-class societal groups traditionally favor lean welfare states, smaller government spending, balanced budgets and lower taxes and inflation (Castro and Martins, 2019; Nguyen et al., 2020; McManus, 2019). Thus, we conjecture that left-wing governments may spend more during elections than right-wing governments. Table 8 explores this dimension by interacting electoral variables with a dummy variable of left-wing government (Left-wing). We find that left-wing governments are associated with higher government spending, which supports the extensive literature on partisan models of government expenditure (Magkonis et al., 2021).

The interaction term in Column 1 of Table 8 indicates that the positive impact of Pre-election on government spending is strengthened when left-wing governments stay in office. The finding implies that left-wing governments increase their spending in the year before an election by a higher amount than right-wing governments, which is consistent with Veiga and Veiga (2007). As governments tend to pursue core policy orientation and party cohesion (Sacchi and Roh, 2016), right-wing governments may have less motivation to expand government spending before an election than left-wing governments aggressively. Nevertheless, we do not find evidence that left-wing governments have an essential impact on government spending in the election year and the year after an election.

4.7 The role of democracy

The political budget cycle theory suggests that incumbent governments act opportunistically to increase the chance of re-election (Nordhaus, 1975; Alesina et al., 1997). This theory relies on the political-market imperfections, which implies that opportunistic behavior exists due to information asymmetries between incumbent governments and voters (Vergne, 2009). In particular, due to information asymmetries, voters tend to rely on observed information about government spending before an election to make inferences about the persistence of incumbents' competence over time (Shi and Svensson, 2006). However, opportunistic behavior could be less pronounced in more democratic countries. Democracy, by promoting political competition, helps to alleviate adverse selection phenomena and asymmetry information (Rogoff, 1990; Vergne, 2009).

Moreover, in more democratic countries, voters are more fiscal conservations (Peltzman, 1992). They are aware of manipulated fiscal policies and punish incumbents for higher deficits and spending before an election (Peltzman, 1992; Brender and Drazen, 2008). These arguments lead us to conjecture that democracy may alleviate the effects of political budget cycles.

Using data for the level of democracy from the Polity IV database, we interact democracy (Democracy) with electoral variables. Table 9 shows that the effects of Pre-election and Election on government spending become smaller at higher levels of democracy, firmly confirming that democracy reduces opportunistic behavior before and during election years.

4.8 Alternative clustering standard errors

As election variables vary between countries, standard errors are clustered at the country level throughout this paper. To ease any concern that our findings are sensitive to changes in underlying structures of standard errors, in Table 10, we employ two-way clustering standard errors at both country and year. We also account for country-fixed effects, which helps to control for unobserved time-invariant differences between countries, such as public policies, institutions and culture. In general, we find that the effects of electoral variables on government spending are consistent with the results of the baseline models, firmly indicating that our results are robust to more complex structures of standard errors and inclusion of country-fixed effects.

5. Addressing endogeneity concerns

There might be concerns that our findings presented so far suffer from serious endogeneity problems. It is worth stressing that election variables are less likely to be influenced by endogeneity issues as they are predetermined and well distributed based on the chief executive's term. Thus, election years are generally exogenous political events (Kaviani et al., 2020). Moreover, as far as we are concerned, no previous study provides theoretical or empirical evidence on the reverse relationship between government expenditure and the election cycle.

However, government expenditure could persist over time, indicating that not including the lagged dependent variable in our regressions could result in omitted variable bias (Nguyen, 2021b). Nevertheless, the inclusion of the lagged dependent variable will mislead OLS estimates due to the correlation between the lagged dependent variable and the error term (Baltagi, 2013; Bermpei et al., 2018). For this reason, we employ a two-step system GMM model proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundel and Bond (1998). In our GMM setting, we treat only lagged dependent variables and election variables as endogeneity as they are our main variables of interest. Control variables enter our regressions lagged one year to alleviate endogeneity. We treat control variables as exogenous to reduce the number of instruments and avoid the problems of too many instruments.

Table 11 presents our results using the GMM approach. The lagged dependent variable enters statistically significant at the 1% level in all models, confirming the necessity to account for dynamic effects. Since Hansen and Arellano-Bond autocorrelation tests never reject the validity of our instruments used, it is safe to assume that our GMM estimates are valid. The positive and significant coefficients on Pre-election and Election confirm the political budget cycles and our evidence presented above. Similarly, we continue to find that governments reduce their spending in the year after an election. The magnitude of coefficients on election variables and control variables do not change much in comparison with those presented in our baseline models, suggesting that endogeneity and omitted variable bias do not significantly influence our main findings.

6. Conclusion

This study contributes to the literature by exploring the political budget cycles in emerging and developing countries. We find that incumbent governments act opportunistically before and during an election by increasing government spending to generate nomination benefits, confirming the existence of the political budget cycles in emerging and developing economies. In particular, incumbents increase spending – especially spending on economic affairs – in the year before an election. At the same time, they contract spending in the year after an election to correct imbalances generated before. These findings are robust to alternative clustering standard errors and endogeneity problems.

Given that opportunistic behavior results in some negative effects, as they are driven by political purposes rather than social welfare, our findings suggest that policymakers in emerging and developing countries should be aware of the opportunistic behavior of incumbent governments during an election cycle. Besides, the presence of right-wing governments and promoting control of corruption and democracy are useful to alleviate the effects of the political budget cycles.

Due to the availability of data for elections, we do not account for legislative and do not differentiate between scheduled and unscheduled elections. Future research should explore these dimensions to provide a more complete picture of political budget cycles.

Variable definition

Dependent variables
ExpenditureThe share of total government expenditure to GDPGovernment Finance Statistics (GFS) – IMF
Economic affairsThe ratio of government spending on economic affairs to GDPGFS
Public servicesThe ratio of government spending on public services to GDPGFS
Social welfareThe ratio of government spending on social welfare to GDP. Social welfare is the sum of government spending on health, education and social protectionGFS
Main independent variables
Pre-electionThe dummy variable which equals 1 for the year before an election and 0 otherwiseDatabase of Political Institutions (DPI)
ElectionThe dummy variable which equals 1 for election years and 0 otherwiseDPI
Post-electionThe dummy variable which equals 1 for the year after an election and 0 otherwiseDPI
Control variables
Population growthThe annual growth rate of the total population in a countryWorld Development Indicators (WDI)
Median ageThe median age of the entire population of a countryUnited Nations
GDP growthThe annual GDP growth rate of a countryWDI
Unemployment rateThe unemployment rate of a countryWDI
InflationThe annual inflation rate, which is based on the consumer price indexWDI
Government debtThe ratio of general government debt to GDP. In the case that data for general government debt are missing, we use central government debtWDI
Tax revenueThe index measures the overall level of economic freedom with higher values indicating greater levels of freedomWDI
Corruption controlThe index measures the level of control of corruption in a country. The index varies between −2.5 and 2.5, with higher values indicating stronger control of corruptionWorld Governance Indicators
Left-wingThe dummy variable which equals 1 if the incumbent government is characterized as left-wing and 0 otherwiseDPI
DemocracyThe index (polity2) measures overall level of democracy. The index varies between −10 (hereditary monarchy) and 10 (consolidated democracy), with higher values indicating higher levels of democracyPOLITY IV

Source(s): Authors' own work

Descriptive statistics

VariableObsMeanStd. devMinMax
Expenditure1,44125.9311.806.69102.25
Public services1,1166.444.021.1732.08
Economic affairs1,1254.592.970.5319.11
Social welfare1,22710.987.050.5231.24
Pre-election1,4410.200.4001
Election1,4410.210.4101
Post-election1,4110.210.4101
Population growth1,4411.341.23−1.736.05
Median age1,44125.327.3713.5943.53
Unemployment rate1,4417.955.960.5230.69
Inflation1,44110.1124.01−2.92432.79
Government debt1,44148.6333.532.95215.97
GDP growth1,4412.893.93−15.0415.31
Tax revenue1,44114.875.490.0434.63
Corruption control1,240−0.260.69−1.671.71
Left-wing1,1110.4580.49801
Democracy1,3354.3845.682−1010

Note(s): Ninety-one countries considered in this study include Afghanistan, Albania, Angola, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bahamas, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Barbados, Belarus, Bhutan, Bolivia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Botswana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cabo Verde, Cambodia, Central African Republic, Chile, China, Colombia, Congo Republic, Costa Rica, Cote d’Ivoire, Croatia, Dominican Republic, Egypt, El Salvador, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Georgia, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Hungary, India, Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan, Kenya, Korea, Kuwait, Kyrgyz Republic, Lebanon, Liberia, Madagascar, Malaysia, Maldives, Mauritius, Mexico, Moldova, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar, Namibia, Nepal, Nicaragua, North Macedonia, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Romania, Russian Federation, Saudi Arabia, Solomon Islands, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Sudan, Tajikistan, Tanzania, Thailand, Togo, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkiye, Uganda, Ukraine, United Arab Emirates, Uruguay, Vanuatu and Zambia

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and expenditure: baseline results

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pre-election1.753*** 1.613***
(0.639) (0.524)
Election 1.044*** 1.276***
(0.353) (0.462)
Post-election −1.226**−1.280**
(0.578)(0.598)
Population growth (t – 1)1.388*1.384*1.375*1.312*
(0.772)(0.771)(0.774)(0.776)
Median age (t – 1)0.606***0.605***0.604***0.602***
(0.196)(0.197)(0.197)(0.196)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.483***0.483***0.483***0.483***
(0.167)(0.167)(0.167)(0.167)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.258***−0.249***−0.264***−0.253***
(0.0570)(0.0581)(0.0569)(0.0568)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0644***−0.0860***−0.0588**−0.0595**
(0.0241)(0.0240)(0.0240)(0.0239)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.1650.1650.1630.162
(0.148)(0.148)(0.148)(0.148)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.422**0.423**0.422**0.428**
(0.188)(0.187)(0.188)(0.186)
Constant1.863***1.825***1.792***1.816***
(0.294)(0.586)(0.412)(0.427)
Observations1,4411,4411,4411,441
Time effectsYesYesYesYes
Number of countries91919191
R-squared0.2860.2860.2860.289

Note(s): Robust standard errors clustered by country are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government spending to GDP (Expenditure). ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and economic affairs

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pre-election0.970*** 0.884***
(0.281) (0.272)
Election 0.727*** 0.771***
(0.215) (0.246)
Post-election −0.605**−0.559**
(0.312)(0.282)
Population growth (t – 1)−0.278**−0.257**−0.261**−0.285**
(0.138)(0.126)(0.128)(0.122)
Median age (t – 1)0.346***0.345***0.365***0.334***
(0.0974)(0.0974)(0.0975)(0.0974)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)−0.0346−0.0146−0.0146−0.0139
(0.0496)(0.0496)(0.0494)(0.0489)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.122***−0.148***−0.196***−0.155**
(0.0435)(0.0535)(0.0612)(0.0654)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.00983*−0.00991*−0.00986**−0.0104*
(0.00495)(0.00594)(0.00495)(0.00582)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.0979**0.0984**0.0982**0.0976**
(0.0427)(0.0428)(0.0427)(0.0422)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.231***0.234***0.230***0.248***
(0.0494)(0.0493)(0.0493)(0.0487)
Constant4.410**4.409**4.450**4.520**
(2.246)(2.248)(2.258)(2.215)
Observations1,1251,1251,1251,125
Time effectsYesYesYesYes
Number of countries76767676
R-squared0.0710.0720.0730.078

Note(s): Robust standard errors clustered by country are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of government spending on economic affairs to GDP (Economic affairs). ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and general public services

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pre-election0.277*** 0.319***
(0.0567) (0.0777)
Election 0.120*** 0.149***
(0.0319) (0.0346)
Post-election 0.162−0.223
(0.114)(0.172)
Population growth (t – 1)0.326***0.329***0.323***0.307***
(0.0882)(0.0864)(0.0851)(0.0821)
Median age (t – 1)−0.108**−0.106**−0.110**−0.106**
(0.0482)(0.0483)(0.0481)(0.0479)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.03820.03790.03780.0386
(0.0538)(0.0538)(0.0537)(0.0539)
Inflation (t – 1)0.02590.02600.02610.0258
(0.0160)(0.0160)(0.0158)(0.0157)
Government debt (t – 1)0.0357***0.0357***0.0357***0.0354***
(0.0110)(0.0109)(0.0109)(0.0110)
GDP growth (t – 1)−0.0392−0.0387−0.0389−0.0394
(0.0543)(0.0544)(0.0543)(0.0542)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.158**0.158**0.158**0.159**
(0.0759)(0.0760)(0.0759)(0.0754)
Constant4.004***4.969***4.014***3.212
(1.675)(1.669)(1.669)(2.628)
Observations1,1161,1161,1161,116
Time effectsYesYesYesYes
Number of countries76767676
R-squared0.2620.2620.2620.264

Note(s): Robust standard errors clustered by country are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of government spending on public services to GDP (Public services). ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and social welfare

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Pre-election0.620*** 0.678***
(0.113) (0.149)
Election 0.813*** 0.942***
(0.205) (0.286)
Post-election −0.559***−0.588***
(0.125)(0.145)
Population growth (t – 1)0.474**0.469***0.461***0.468**
(0.230)(0.230)(0.230)(0.236)
Median age (t – 1)0.529***0.530***0.530***0.577***
(0.161)(0.162)(0.161)(0.106)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.129*0.129*0.128*0.184**
(0.0688)(0.0687)(0.0683)(0.0923)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.0155**−0.0154**−0.0155**−0.0156**
(0.00672)(0.00672)(0.00664)(0.00701)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0128**−0.0128**−0.0128**−0.0128**
(0.00518)(0.00517)(0.00519)(0.00519)
GDP growth (t – 1)−0.0424*−0.0426*−0.0428*−0.0636
(0.0227)(0.0227)(0.0226)(0.0664)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.159**0.160**0.160**0.195**
(0.0671)(0.0671)(0.0670)(0.0904)
Constant−5.038***−5.134***−5.132***−8.881***
(1.297)(1.314)(1.310)(3.283)
Observations1,2271,2271,2271,227
Time effectsYesYesYesYes
Number of countries83838383
R-squared0.5600.5720.5630.583

Note(s): Robust standard errors clustered by country are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of government spending on social welfare to GDP (Social welfare). ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and public spending: the role of control of corruption

(1)(2)(3)
Pre-election2.131***
(0.765)
Pre-election × Corruption control−0.420***
(0.133)
Election 1.460***
(0.446)
Election × Corruption control −0.223***
(0.0598)
Post-election −1.225**
(0.597)
Post-election × Corruption control −1.559
(1.220)
Corruption control−0.528**−0.612**−0.592**
(0.249)(0.300)(0.281)
Population growth (t – 1)2.638***2.632***2.618***
(0.841)(0.845)(0.846)
Median age (t – 1)0.840***0.839***0.838***
(0.197)(0.199)(0.199)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.523***0.520***0.523***
(0.186)(0.187)(0.187)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.158***−0.161***−0.149***
(0.0455)(0.0424)(0.0510)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0222−0.0226−0.0223
(0.0268)(0.0272)(0.0271)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.1890.1930.191
(0.161)(0.164)(0.162)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.583***0.576***0.575***
(0.189)(0.192)(0.192)
Constant4.75***5.16***4.93***
(1.803)(1.915)(1.846)
Observations1,2401,2401,240
Time effectsYesYesYes
Number of countries909090
R-squared0.3410.3360.337

Note(s): The table reports the conditioning effects of control of corruption (Corruption control) on the relationship between the election cycle and government spending. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP (Expenditure). Standard errors clustered at the country level are in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and public spending: the role of political ideology

(1)(2)(3)
Pre-election0.612***
(0.220)
Pre-election × Left-wing0.356**
(0.172)
Election 1.375**
(0.588)
Election × Left-wing 0.205
(0.239)
Post-election −0.601***
(0.231)
Post-election × Left-wing 0.704
(0.818)
Left-wing2.654**2.433**2.410**
(1.164)(1.116)(1.104)
Population growth (t – 1)1.372***1.376***1.379***
(0.441)(0.435)(0.431)
Median age (t – 1)0.766***0.765***0.765***
(0.222)(0.222)(0.222)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.349**0.348**0.348**
(0.132)(0.132)(0.132)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.0114−0.0116−0.0117
(0.0138)(0.0139)(0.0141)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0200−0.0200−0.0201
(0.0258)(0.0257)(0.0257)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.07730.07700.0804
(0.106)(0.107)(0.107)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.667***0.668***0.669***
(0.162)(0.162)(0.162)
Constant3.593.553.60
(2.610)(2.568)(2.558)
Observations1,1111,1111,111
Time effectsYesYesYes
Number of countries757575
R-squared0.4110.4110.411

Note(s): The table reports the conditioning effects of left-wing government (Left-wing) on the relationship between the election cycle and government spending. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP (Expenditure). Standard errors clustered at the country level are in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and public spending: the role of democracy

(1)(2)(3)
Pre-election1.007***
(0.368)
Pre-election × Democracy−0.234**
(0.0961)
Election 0.637**
(0.311)
Election × Democracy −0.255**
(0.124)
Post-election −1.067**
(0.499)
Post-election × Democracy 0.176
(0.135)
Democracy−0.602***−0.601***−0.589***
(0.164)(0.152)(0.150)
Population growth (t – 1)0.628**0.624**0.635**
(0.278)(0.267)(0.274)
Median age (t – 1)0.634***0.633***0.635***
(0.188)(0.187)(0.187)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.441**0.440**0.440**
(0.173)(0.173)(0.173)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.150***−0.151***−0.143***
(0.0431)(0.0431)(0.0434)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0438**−0.0486**−0.0468**
(0.0218)(0.0217)(0.0218)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.02350.02110.0193
(0.141)(0.140)(0.142)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.626***0.627***0.628***
(0.180)(0.180)(0.180)
Constant−0.775−0.807−1.003
(6.811)(6.734)(6.699)
Observations1,3351,3351,335
Time effectsYesYesYes
Number of countries868686
R-squared0.3750.3760.375

Note(s): The table reports the conditioning effects of democracy (Democracy) on the relationship between the election cycle and government spending. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP (Expenditure). Standard errors clustered at the country level are in parentheses. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and expenditure: alternative clustering standard errors

(1)(2)(3)
Pre-election1.255***
(0.387)
Election 0.832***
(0.256)
Post-election −0.918***
(0.345)
Population growth (t – 1)0.858***0.895***0.828***
(0.250)(0.244)(0.247)
Median age (t – 1)0.697***0.698***0.699***
(0.166)(0.166)(0.167)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.181**0.181**0.180**
(0.0877)(0.0880)(0.0875)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.180**−0.0181**−0.0183**
(0.0818)(0.00832)(0.00823)
Government debt (t – 1)−0.0886***−0.0885***−0.0885***
(0.0234)(0.0234)(0.0234)
GDP growth (t – 1)−0.0117−0.0114−0.0112
(0.0490)(0.0487)(0.0488)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.355***0.355***0.356***
(0.0916)(0.0913)(0.0912)
Constant2.5232.5152.451
(3.236)(3.102)(3.122)
Observations1,4401,4401,440
Time effectsYesYesYes
Country effectsYesYesYes
Number of countries919191
R-squared0.8240.8240.824
Cluster levelsCountry and yearCountry and yearCountry and year

Note(s): Robust standard errors clustered by country and year are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP (Expenditure). ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

The election cycle and government spending: GMM model

(1)(2)(3)
L.Expenditure0.757***0.758***0.787***
(0.0831)(0.0799)(0.0804)
Pre-election1.672**
(0.521)
Election 1.105***
(0.326)
Post-election −1.331***
(0.373)
Population growth (t – 1)0.477**0.598***0.572**
(0.192)(0.232)(0.240)
Median age (t – 1)0.173**0.185**0.167**
(0.0735)(0.0731)(0.0675)
Unemployment rate (t – 1)0.101**0.109**0.0967**
(0.0457)(0.0477)(0.0482)
Inflation (t – 1)−0.144***−0.163***−0.175***
(0.0341)(0.0461)(0.0533)
Government debt (t – 1)0.00228−0.00131−0.000708
(0.00601)(0.00591)(0.00581)
GDP growth (t – 1)0.153**0.136**0.144**
(0.0649)(0.0681)(0.0675)
Tax revenue (t – 1)0.518***0.542***0.522***
(0.142)(0.153)(0.129)
Constant3.659***3.873***3.029**
(1.337)(1.510)(1.441)
Observations1,4191,4191,419
Time effectsYesYesYes
Number of countries919191
Number of instruments676767
AR(2)0.1740.1860.193
Hansen J0.4740.4830.425

Note(s): Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The dependent variable is the ratio of total government expenditure to GDP (Expenditure). Time effects in our GMM setting is time trend, which is captured by a trend variable that begins in 1991 and increases by one in each of subsequent years for each country. We also use time trend instead of time-fixed effects to lower the number of instruments in our GMM estimations. ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors' own work

List of countries

AfghanistanCabo VerdeGuatemalaMexicoRussian Federation
AlbaniaCambodiaHondurasMoldovaSaudi Arabia
AngolaCameroonHungaryMongoliaSolomon Islands
ArmeniaCentral African RepublicIndiaMoroccoSouth Africa
AzerbaijanChileIranMozambiqueSri Lanka
BahamasChinaJamaicaMyanmarSudan
BahrainColombiaJordanNamibiaTajikistan
BangladeshCongo RepublicKazakhstanNepalTanzania
BarbadosCosta RicaKenyaNicaraguaThailand
BelarusCote d’IvoireKoreaNorth MacedoniaTogo
BhutanCroatiaKuwaitPakistanTrinidad and Tobago
BoliviaDominican RepublicKyrgyz RepublicPanamaTunisia
Bosnia and HerzegovinaEgyptLebanonPapua New GuineaTurkiye
BotswanaEl SalvadorLiberiaParaguayUganda
BrazilEquatorial GuineaMadagascarPeruUkraine
BulgariaEthiopiaMalaysiaPhilippinesUnited Arab Emirates
Burkina FasoGeorgiaMaldivesPolandUruguay
BurundiGhanaMauritiusRomaniaVanuatu
Zambia

Source(s): Authors' own work

Correlation matrix

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)(11)(12)(13)(14)
Expenditure(1)1
Public services(2)0.361
Economic affairs(3)0.530.051
Social welfare(4)0.770.000.221
Pre-election(5)0.01−0.05−0.020.031
Election(6)0.00−0.04−0.020.04−0.181
Post-election(7)−0.01−0.04−0.040.03−0.22−0.191
Population(8)−0.300.17−0.07−0.54−0.05−0.07−0.081
Median age(9)0.39−0.180.080.680.040.060.05−0.781
Unemployment rate(10)0.360.17−0.030.320.030.020.01−0.120.091
Inflation(11)0.020.23−0.06−0.01−0.03−0.030.03−0.02−0.050.041
Government debt(12)−0.040.38−0.16−0.13−0.04−0.07−0.030.16−0.170.100.141
GDP growth(13)0.03−0.170.150.030.020.02−0.01−0.230.15−0.10−0.15−0.141
Tax revenue(14)0.400.190.060.480.040.050.03−0.280.290.310.060.01−0.051

Source(s): Authors' own work

Notes

1.

The list of countries considered in this study is provided at the footnote of Table 2.

2.

Results are not reported here but are available upon request.

3.

Our findings remain consistent when we use the annual growth rate of government spending instead of the level of government spending. The results are not reported here but are available upon request.

Appendix

References

Aklin, M. and Kern, A. (2021), “The side effects of central bank independence”, American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 65 No. 4, pp. 971-987.

Alesina, A., Roubini, N. and Cohen, G.D. (1997), Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy, MIT Press, MA.

Alesina, A., Perotti, R. and Tavares, J. (1998), “The political economy of fiscal adjustments”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1998 No. 1, pp. 197-266.

Ames, B. (1977), “The politics of public spending in Latin America”, American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 149-176.

Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995), “Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68, pp. 29-51.

Baltagi, B. (2013), Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, 5th ed., John Wiley & Sons, Chichester.

Barberia, L.G., Avelino, G., Eslava, M. and Streb, J.M. (2011), “Do political budget cycles differ in Latin American democracies?”, Economia, Vol. 11 No. 2, pp. 101-146.

Bermpei, T., Kalyvas, A. and Nguyen, T.C. (2018), “Does institutional quality condition the effect of bank regulations and supervision on bank stability? Evidence from emerging and developing economies”, International Review of Financial Analysis, Vol. 59, pp. 255-275.

Block, S.A. (2001), “Elections, electoral competitiveness, and political budget cycles in developing countries”, CID Working Paper Series 2001.78, Center for International Development, Harvard University.

Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998), “Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 87, pp. 115-143.

Bonfatti, A. and Forni, L. (2019), “Fiscal rules to tame the political budget cycle”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 60, 101800.

Brender, A. and Drazen, A. (2008), “How do budget deficits and economic growth affect re-election prospects? Evidence from a large panel of countries”, American Economic Review, Vol. 98 No. 5, pp. 2203-2220.

Brender, A. and Drazen, A. (2013), “Elections, leaders, and the composition of government spending”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 97, pp. 18-31.

Castro, V. and Martins, R. (2013), “Running for office again: evidence from Portuguese municipal elections”, Public Choice, Vol. 156, pp. 677-702.

Castro, V. and Martins, R. (2019), “Political and institutional determinants of credit booms”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 81 No. 5, pp. 1144-1178.

Coviello, D. and Gagliarducci, S. (2017), “Tenure in office and public procurement”, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 59-105.

Devarajan, S., Swaroop, V. and Zou, H. (1996), “The composition of public expenditure and economic growth”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 313-344.

Drazen, A. and Eslava, M. (2010), “Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: theory and evidence”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 39-52.

Foremny, D. and Riedel, N. (2014), “Business taxes and the electoral cycle”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 115, pp. 48-61.

Garriga, A.C. (2016), “Central bank independence in the world: a new data set”, International Interactions, Vol. 42 No. 5, pp. 849-868.

Hibbs, D.A. (1977), “Political parties and macroeconomic policy”, American Political Science Review, Vol. 71, pp. 1467-1487.

Holcombe, R.G. and Williams, D.W. (2008), “The impact of population density on municipal government expenditures”, Public Finance Review, Vol. 36 No. 3, pp. 359-373.

Katsimi, M. and Sarantides, V. (2012), “Do elections affect the composition of fiscal policy in developed, established democracies?”, Public Choice, Vol. 151 No. 1, pp. 325-362.

Kaviani, M.S., Kryzanowski, L., Maleki, H. and Savor, P. (2020), “Policy uncertainty and corporate credit spreads”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 138, pp. 838-865.

Klein, F.A. and Sukurai, S.N. (2015), “Term limits and political budget cycles at the local level: evidence from a young democracy”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 37, pp. 21-36.

Lewis, B. (2018), “Local government form in Indonesia: tax, expenditure, and efficiency effects”, Studies in Comparative International Development, Vol. 53 No. 1, pp. 25-46.

Lindvall, J. (2014), “The electoral consequences of two great crises”, European Journal of Political Research, Vol. 53, pp. 747-765.

Magkonis, G., Zekente, K.M. and Logothetis, V. (2021), “Does the left spend more? An econometric survey of partisan politics”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 83 No. 4, pp. 1077-1099.

Mauro, P. (1998), “Corruption and the composition of government expenditure”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 69, pp. 263-279.

McManus, I.P. (2019), “The re-emergence of partisan effects on social spending after the Global Financial Crisis”, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 57 No. 6, pp. 1274-1291.

Nguyen, T.C. (2021a), “Economic policy uncertainty and bank stability: does bank regulation and supervision matter in major European economies?”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, Vol. 74, 101387.

Nguyen, T.C. (2021b), “The effects of financial crisis on income inequality”, Development Policy Review, Vol. 40, e12600.

Nguyen, T.C., Castro, V. and Wood, J. (2020), “Political environment and financial crises”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 417-438.

Nguyen, T.C., Castro, V. and Wood, J. (2021), “Financial crises and human development”, Working Paper, doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3802418.

Nguyen, T.C., Castro, V. and Wood, J. (2022a), “Financial crises and social spending”, Working Paper, available at: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4045209

Nguyen, T.C., Castro, V. and Wood, J. (2022b), “Political economy of financial crisis duration”, Public Choice, Vol. 192, pp. 309-330.

Nordhaus, W. (1975), “The political business cycle”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42 No. 2, pp. 169-190.

Parui, P. (2021), “Government expenditure and economic growth: a post-Keynesian analysis”, International Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 35, pp. 597-625.

Peltzman, S. (1992), “Voters as fiscal conservatives”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107 No. 2, pp. 327-361.

Pierskalla, J.H. and Sacks, A. (2018), “Unpaved road ahead: the consequences of election cycles for capital expenditure”, Journal of Politics, Vol. 80 No. 2, pp. 1-15.

Rogoff, K. (1990), “Equilibrium political budget cycles”, American Economic Review, Vol. 80 No. 1, pp. 21-36.

Sacchi, S. and Roh, J. (2016), “Conditionality, austerity and welfare: financial crisis and its impact on welfare in Italy and Korea”, Journal of European Social Policy, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 358-373.

Schneider, C.J. (2010), “Fighting with one hand tied behind the back: political budget cycles in the West German states”, Public Choice, Vol. 142, pp. 125-150.

Schuknecht, L. (2000), “Fiscal policy cycles and public expenditure in developing countries”, Public Choice, Vol. 102, pp. 115-130.

Shi, M. and Svensson, J. (2006), “Political budget cycles: do they differ across countries and why?”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 90, pp. 1367-1389.

Veiga, L.G. and Veiga, F.J. (2007), “Political business cycles at the municipal level”, Public Choice, Vol. 131, pp. 45-64.

Vergne, C. (2009), “Democracy, elections and allocation of public expenditures in developing countries”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 63-77.

Vukovic, V. (2020), “Corruption and re-election: how much can politicians steal before getting punished?”, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 124-143.

Corresponding author

Thanh Cong Nguyen can be contacted at: cong.nguyenthanh@phenikaa-uni.edu.vn

Related articles