Abolishing the Act on System of Choice in Swedish eldercare: on arguments and replacements in the municipalities

David Feltenius (Department of Political Science, Umeå University, Umeå, Sweden)
Jessika Wide (Department of Political Science, Umeå University, Umeå, Sweden)

International Journal of Public Sector Management

ISSN: 0951-3558

Article publication date: 13 December 2023

Issue publication date: 29 February 2024

444

Abstract

Purpose

Since 2009 Swedish municipalities may apply the Act on System of Choice (LOV) in, among other things, eldercare. About half of the 290 Swedish municipalities have chosen this within home-care services for older citizens, thus creating conditions for a welfare mix where private and public providers compete. Some of these municipalities later made decisions to abolish LOV. This article aims to analyse the arguments put forward by municipal politicians to abolish LOV and discusses if the case of abandoning LOV represents a case of re-municipalization.

Design/methodology/approach

Qualitative method was used to analyse decision protocols and media materials from 20 Swedish municipalities that had abolished LOV in home-care services.

Findings

The article shows that politics and ideology seem to have only a limited significance in abolishing LOV. The most important arguments found in the empirical materials were instead pragmatic and related to the transaction costs: in smaller municipalities about the weak position of private providers and in larger municipalities about reported cases of welfare crime and extensive needs to control and review. In smaller municipalities, LOV was replaced by public monopoly and in larger municipalities by other types of procurements.

Originality/value

With its focus on eldercare in party-dominated municipalities, the article adds knowledge to the literature on drivers of re-municipalization but also discusses possible delimitations of the concept of re-municipalization.

Keywords

Citation

Feltenius, D. and Wide, J. (2024), "Abolishing the Act on System of Choice in Swedish eldercare: on arguments and replacements in the municipalities", International Journal of Public Sector Management, Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 141-158. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJPSM-04-2023-0128

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, David Feltenius and Jessika Wide

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


Introduction

Elements of new public management (NPM) and marketization have pervasively changed the Swedish welfare state and thus also the eldercare (Vabø and Szebehely, 2012; Feltenius, 2017; Moberg, 2017, 2023; Blix and Jordahl, 2021; Blomqvist and Winblad, 2022). In Sweden, eldercare, tax-funded and a municipal area of responsibility, mainly consists of nursing homes and home-care services [1]. Since 2009 the Act on System of Choice in the Public Sector (LOV) has given Swedish municipalities the right to decide about introducing so-called “choice systems” in, among other things, eldercare. In 2023 more than half of the Swedish municipalities have a system of choice in operation in home-care services, where private and public providers compete in most cases.

Simultaneously international research pays attention to the fact that marketization and privatization in the public sector are not irreversible nor a lineal development (e.g., Bel et al., 2018; Voorn et al., 2021; Berlin et al., 2023). The case of LOV in Sweden is no exception. Only two years after the introduction of the new act, in 2011, one municipality decided to abolish user choice according to LOV in home-care services (henceforth referred to as abolishing LOV). To date, 23 municipalities have decided to abolish LOV.

In the literature, abolishing LOV has been discussed as a possible case of “re-municipalization” (Montin, 2016; Jordahl and Persson, 2021). The concept suggests that the provision of services returns from the private sector back to the municipal sector – that is, a return to the status as before the privatization (Bönker et al., 2016; Voorn, 2021). But then why does this return happen? International research makes a categorization in two different drivers behind re-municipalization: political drivers including ideological statements against privatization and private providers, and pragmatic drivers including transaction costs, management and quality (e.g., Clifton et al., 2021; Voorn et al., 2021; Albalate et al., 2022; Warner, 2023). According to the literature, pragmatic drivers appear to dominate regarding technical services and infrastructure. Some scholars suggest that ideology could be more evident as a driver concerning social services (Petersen et al., 2015; Gradus and Budding, 2020).

Hence, it could be assumed that political drivers would be prominent for abolishing LOV in eldercare in Sweden, a country also with party-dominated municipalities since municipal politics is organized through the political parties. With few exceptions, the parties in the Swedish municipalities are the same as at national level (Lidström, 2012). If political drivers are frequent, homecare would probably represent a clear-cut case of re-municipalization describing a transfer from the private sector back to the municipal sector. However, if it turns out that homecare is not that different from other sectors such as technical services, and that pragmatic drivers are salient, another important question arises – namely, what happens afterwards? It might not necessarily imply a total “backsourcing” of the provision (see Warner, 2008). Rather, other regulatory systems for sustaining private elements could be introduced, thus with the possible preservation of a “welfare mix” of both private and public providers (Ascoli and Ranci, 2002).

We argue that it is urgent not only to explore drivers behind the abolition of a regulatory system for privatization such as LOV. It is also important to investigate more in detail what replaces it (cf. Voorn et al., 2021). Instead of returning to the previous public monopoly, it might be the case that marketization is maintained by other regulatory tools. If so, the abolition of LOV as a possible case of re-municipalization might be questioned – at least based on the current definition of re-municipalization, with a focus exclusively on ownership and provision.

In this article, we examine the abolition of LOV in home-care services in Swedish municipalities. We address two questions: First, what are the arguments for the abolition of LOV as stated in the municipalities – political, pragmatic or both? Second, does the abolition of LOV, after also having considered what replaces it, represent a case of re-municipalization?

Next, we introduce the Swedish case. Thereafter the concept of “re-municipalization” is introduced. We then discuss our research method and empirical materials, after which we present our findings. In the final and concluding section, we discuss the results and our contribution to the literature.

The Swedish case

Sweden is divided into 290 municipalities with extensive areas of responsibility within welfare (Lidström, 2012). Local self-government is strong, also in statutory and mandatory social services such as eldercare. The principle of local self-government gives Swedish municipalities the right to decide about the marketization of, for example, eldercare and to choose between two different models for procurement (Feltenius and Wide, 2023).

The first model derives from the Public Procurement Act (LOU), originating in the 1990s and which, with its current design, is based on European Union Directive 2004/18/EC (Bretzer et al., 2016). In LOU, the contract is awarded to the provider with the most attractive bid concerning the quality as well as costs of services – or one of the two. In Swedish eldercare, LOU has mainly been applied in the procurement of nursing homes (Feltenius, 2017; Segaard and Saglie, 2017; Lindmark et al., 2023).

The other model is based on the Act on System of Choice in the Public Sector (LOV), a national law from 2009. It is voluntary for the municipalities to apply LOV within a social service area, e.g., eldercare. In LOV there is freedom of establishment. All private providers who meet the requirements stated in the municipality's tender document are allowed to sign a contract with the municipality and then become eligible in a system of choice. The citizens who have been granted home-care services choose which provider will carry out their efforts (Feltenius and Wide, 2019). The municipalities cannot influence the number of providers or the market share of the various providers, for example, they cannot determine what proportion of users will have private home-care services. Instead, the distribution among public and private providers depends on the citizens' choices as well as the interest of private companies to apply for approval. The idea behind LOV was, among other things, that citizens' preferences and not political priorities should govern the organization of welfare services and accordingly strengthen the power of the individual citizen (Government Bill, 2008). In LOV, the approved providers receive a fixed sum from the municipality, based on, for instance, the number of granted hours of service provided each month. The citizen's fee is also fixed and paid to the municipality but covers only a minor portion of the total cost – about 6% (Socialstyrelsen, 2014). The remaining cost is financed by the municipalities through local income taxes as well as central government grants.

In 2010, the first 45 municipalities implemented LOV into operation. In 2023, 159 municipalities had LOV in operation in at least one social service area. Figure 1 shows the development over time. Statistics by type of service are not available over time for LOV in operation, which means that all service areas are included in the figure. However, almost all municipalities that have adopted LOV have done so within home-care services meaning that the figure gives a good overview of the development. There are only one or two municipalities per year that instead only have LOV within, for example, adult daily activities or companion service (SKR, 2018, 2019, SKR 2023a). In 2011, one municipality decided to abolish LOV in homecare; in 2014, two more municipalities followed. To date, 23 municipalities have made decisions to abandon LOV in home-care services.

Previous research has shown that until 2017 the abolishing municipalities had, on average, smaller populations, lower population density, lower income tax base, older inhabitants, and higher electoral support for left parties than municipalities with LOV in operation (Jordahl and Persson, 2021). In 2023, the small, rural municipalities have been joined by large, urban municipalities (SKR 2023b).

The concept of re-municipalization

During the last decades, much research has focused on privatization, outsourcing and marketization of public services and infrastructure. However, in some cases, the public sector regains ground in the ownership or provision. Therefore, lately, another trend has received attention, described as backsourcing (Young and Macinati, 2012; Thakur-Wernz, 2019; Berlin et al., 2022, 2023), insourcing (Damanpour et al., 2020), reverse privatization (Hefetz and Warner, 2004; Warner, 2008; Warner and Hefetz, 2012), contracting back-in (Hung and Lu, 2022), or–in the case of most relevance here since we are dealing with the local level – re-municipalization (Hall et al., 2013; Bönker et al., 2016; Wollman, 2018; Clifton et al., 2021; Voorn et al., 2021).

The concept of re-municipalization means that the ownership or provision of, for example, services return from the private sector back to the municipal sector – a return to the status as before the privatization. This is evident from the definition provided by Bart Voorn: “remunicipalization refers to the return of previously privatized (or contracted-out) services to municipal authorities” (Voorn, 2021 p. 442). However, there has been some confusion in the literature regarding the concept. Judith Clifton and others have addressed this ambiguity and highlight two important aspects of the concept. Firstly, the development should occur exclusively at the municipal level and not, for example, as a transfer of responsibilities from the national to the municipal level. Secondly, there is a trajectory of transfer from the municipality to the private sector, and then back to the municipality again (see Clifton et al., 2021 pp. 295–297).

This development is also described as a “reverse privatization” since public services are moved away from privatization. It implies that the direction of privatization is not inevitable, linear or irreversible (Clifton et al., 2021). Already a decade ago, re-municipalization was frequent in European countries in – among other things – water, electricity, public transport, waste management and housing (Hall, 2012). Research on local governments in the United States has shown similar patterns (e.g., Hefetz and Warner, 2004; Warner, 2008; Warner and Hefetz, 2012; Damanpour et al., 2020).

Re-municipalization can take several different forms. It includes the creation of municipally owned corporations, the repurchase of shares sold to private companies and the re-insourcing of outsourced services, for example after the expiration of concession contracts (Wollman, 2018; Voorn et al., 2021). Previous research on re-municipalization has mainly dealt with the sectors of energy, waste and water, as well as public transportation. Less research has dealt with social services (Hung and Lu, 2022). One reason might be that in many countries, unlike in Sweden, the municipalities' role in social services is limited. Yet, until recently, research on re-municipalization in a Swedish context has been sparse (but see Jansson et al., 2021; Jordahl and Persson, 2021; Berlin et al., 2022; Carlström et al., 2023).

Drivers behind re-municipalization

The reasons for re-municipalization may vary. In previous research, the “drivers” behind re-municipalization have been divided into two rather broad categories: “political” and “pragmatic” (e.g., Clifton et al., 2021; Albalate et al., 2021; Voorn, 2021; Voorn et al., 2021; Warner and Aldag, 2021; Albalate et al., 2022; Warner, 2023).

Political drivers

Political drivers are based on ideological statements against private providers or private ownership in certain activities and services. For example, it may be an ambition to regain democratic control over critical infrastructure, such as water and energy, or not to let in for-profit providers in tax-funded public services (e.g., Hall, 2012; Clifton et al., 2021; Warner and Aldag, 2021). According to previous research, ideology does not have a substantial effect on re-municipalization (Hanna and McDonald, 2021; Berlin et al., 2023; Warner, 2023). However, it must be noted that party politicization at the local level is low in countries investigated such as the United States (Warner and Aldag, 2021; Warner, 2023) while also social services have been largely neglected in previous research. Instead, the literature has been devoted mainly to technical services and infrastructure such as water and waste services (see Petersen et al., 2015; Gradus and Budding, 2020; Hanna and McDonald, 2021).

In Sweden, privatization in social services has long been an ideological issue and a divider in politics. A common argument by left-wing parties is that tax-financed activities should be carried out by the public sector and not by for-profit companies. Liberal and conservative parties are in general more positive about privatization (Stolt and Winblad, 2009; Guo and Willner, 2017; Hardell et al., 2020), accordingly influencing privatization at the local level (Elinder and Jordahl, 2013a; Lindh and Johansson Sevä, 2018).

Another argument is that privatizations challenge the universalistic and collective core of the Swedish welfare model – that is, accessible, inclusive and equal social services of high quality (e.g., Vabø and Szebehely, 2012). A system of choice might instead contribute to increased inequality since citizens have different conditions to make informed choices and the services of the providers may vary (Moberg et al., 2016; Moberg, 2017, 2023).

Pragmatic drivers

In the literature, pragmatic reasons behind re-municipalization mainly concern management issues and aspirations to reduce transaction costs (e.g., Clifton et al., 2021; Voorn, 2021; Warner and Aldag, 2021; Albalate et al., 2022; Berlin et al., 2023; Warner, 2023). More specifically, pragmatic reasons include efforts to possible efficiency gains, cost savings and quality improvements as well as problems with contract management, monitoring and control (e.g., Voorn, 2021 for a review). Additionally, the literature mentions the absence of private providers and a low level of competition (Jansson et al., 2021).

The transaction costs for privatization in social services should not be underestimated. There are costs of monitoring and evaluating the private providers as well as the contract management itself. If these costs are too large, it may be more economically beneficial to perform the services “in-house”, i.e., only by the public provider (Elinder and Jordahl, 2013b).

In Swedish municipalities with LOV in home-care services, the transaction costs may be unreasonable if there are just a few private providers – or none (Jordahl and Persson, 2021; Jansson et al., 2021; Feltenius and Wide, 2023). Even without any private providers, the costs of administering the choice system remain, for example, to keep the tender document and routines up to date. The same applies if there are just a couple of citizens who choose private providers.

The costs for monitoring and control to ensure quality and avoid sector failures and misconduct may as well be extensive (e.g., Hall, 2012; Jansson et al., 2021). Previous investigations of eldercare have discussed misconduct among private providers as well as major “failures” in eldercare, for example, fraud and elder neglect and abuse (Klingberg Hjort and Martinsson, 2021; Berlin et al., 2022).

Data and methodology

Identifying the municipalities

We used data from the Swedish Association of Local Authorities and Regions (SKR) to find municipalities that have decided to abolish LOV (SKR, 2020, 2023b). Thereafter, to ensure that the decision concerned home-care services and not another area, we contacted each municipality and asked for the date of the decision as well as the relevant decision protocols [2]. We identified 23 municipalities that have abolished LOV in homecare. In three of these municipalities, we failed to obtain decision protocols and other empirical materials whereupon they have been excluded [3]. Accordingly, we investigate 20 municipalities [4].

Empirical materials

We wanted to capture the arguments behind the decision to abolish LOV– what were the stated reasons? Most of the municipalities made their decisions several years ago. The closer in time the source is to what it provides information about, the more credible the information is since people have a strong tendency to either forget or rationalize afterwards. Therefore, instead of conducting interviews long afterwards, we chose to analyse materials contemporary to the political decision.

First, we gathered the municipalities' decision protocols as described above. These contained a decision justification which could be brief or extensive. Some also had supplements, such as investigations. Second, we gathered media materials by using Retriever's digital news archive, which provides articles from print and digital editorial media as well as from radio and television. For each municipality, we conducted searches on the municipality's name in combination with “home-care services” (hemtjänst). Thereafter we selected the material that dealt with the abolition of LOV [5]. Both news articles and debate articles are included.

Information about what has replaced LOV in home-care services – public monopoly or another procurement model – was gathered from the municipalities' websites complemented with media material.

Analytical framework – abolishing LOV

Based on previous research on re-municipalization, we constructed an analytical framework with political and pragmatic arguments and a draft of indicators of reasons for abolishing LOV. After reviewing the empirical materials, we made some adjustments to the indicators to make them clearer and include all arguments appearing in the materials. Thus, our analytical framework was designed through interplay between theory and materials (Table 1). The political reasons include ideological arguments against profits in public welfare and arguments to safeguard universalism. The pragmatic reasons are more diverse and include the weak position of private providers, lack of stability regarding the number of providers, private providers' elder abuse, private providers' fraud, private providers' inadequate routines and, finally, administrative burden to maintain the system of choice.

Analytical framework – replacing LOV

There are two plausible outcomes in the analysis of what LOV had been replaced by (Table 2). The first outcome is homecare only by the public provider, i.e., public monopoly. The other outcome is procurement according to the LOU, i.e., continued privatization. In this case, either all home-care services in the municipality can be procured – or a specified share of it. In the latter case, the municipality keeps a part “in-house.”

Findings

Arguments to abolish LOV in home-care services

In the empirical materials, we searched for indicators of political and pragmatic reasons to abolish LOV in homecare. A summary of the investigation is presented in Table 3 which shows the arguments found in the material from each municipality as well as the municipalities' population. Since the material is different in length and degree of detail between the municipalities, some individual arguments may be missing in the presentation. Overall, however, we assess that the analysis gives a fair picture of municipalities that have abolished LOV.

Political reasons

One finding is that political arguments for abolishing LOV are few in the materials. Only one municipality explicitly mentions problems with profits in welfare, namely the small northern municipality of Robertsfors. The social-democratic chairman states that LOV is not only being abolished for pragmatic reasons but also ideological reasons: “We don't want people to take money out of welfare and give it to private companies. We want people to reinvest back into schools and the elderly” (Västerbottens Folkblad, 2015).

In a few other municipalities, it is stated that in a system with LOV politicians have less opportunity to influence and control eldercare regarding working conditions for the staff or continuity for the users: “There should be as few staff as possible involved with a user. It should be uniform. But we cannot control that if we outsource the work” (Nya Kristinehamns-Posten, 2011). It is also stated in the municipality of Vindeln that it is better to have a municipal provider for all care activities, to ensure the quality of the activities (Västerbottens Folkblad, 2012). We choose to interpret these statements as arguments to safeguard universalism in eldercare, i.e., all citizens should have the same quality of care, regardless of provider.

This means that, in the materials, not much indicates that LOV is abolished for ideological reasons. On the other hand, we find ideological arguments from centre-right politicians who oppose the abolition of LOV. For example, a politician in the municipality of Båstad says: “It's a fundamental ideological issue for us the Moderates, the right to choose, and to keep LOV costs nothing” (Helsingborgs Dagblad, 2016). In a reservation to the decision, the Liberals in the municipality of Södertälje state: “The Act on System of Choice puts the individual senior in the centre. We stand up for LOV” (Södertälje kommun, 2014).

Yet, in many municipalities, centre-right politicians support the abolition of LOV. In some municipalities they are even the driving force, as in Tjörn, an island municipality on the west coast: “It's never fun for a Moderate to say that we have decided to abolish LOV” (Göteborgs-Posten, 2018). Another example is the municipality of Strängnäs: “We cannot automatically continue with a system that doesn't work, just because you stand behind a political view that promotes freedom of choice” (Dagens Samhälle, 2021).

Pragmatic reasons

Pragmatic reasons were frequent in the empirical materials. When we compiled our findings, we noted interesting differences between small and large municipalities (see population size in Table 3): different problems were described, and different arguments were put forward. Especially the larger municipalities Linköping, Sollentuna, and Södertälje deviate. However, common in all municipalities is that the costs of maintaining the system are seen as burdensome concerning administration and supervision. In addition, the municipalities see it as problematic that they cannot influence the number of private providers in LOV due to the principle of free establishment.

A common remark that we find in the material of smaller municipalities is that there have been private providers in the past, but too few citizens have chosen them. Therefore, these providers have closed their operations in the municipalities. In other small municipalities, one or a few private providers remain but with just a few users, and in a few more municipalities there has never been a private provider.

Accordingly, a general statement in the material is that citizens with granted home-care services have not been interested in choosing private providers, but also that private companies are not interested in applying. A typical comment is: “It [LOV] doesn't work in small municipalities” (Skaraborgsbygden, 2017). In some smaller municipalities, the last private provider has just filed for bankruptcy or has not extended its contract for quality reasons. Thus, it was seen as “the right opportunity” to abolish LOV. Another few municipalities have only exceptionally had private providers and chose to abolish LOV rather than spend a lot of administrative time updating the tender document in accordance to current procedures and organization. The materials show that the politicians consider that an extensive administration is required to maintain LOV, mainly to continuously update and revise the tender document and routines. In municipalities with approved private providers, the administration is also required to inform the citizens about selectable providers and how the choice should be made.

One example of a municipality with few users with a private provider is Finspång. The year prior to the decision to abolish LOV, twelve home-care recipients had chosen the sole private provider. This provider completed a total of 38 h out of the municipality's over 10,000 annual home-care hours (Norrköpings Tidningar, 2018). Yet an administrative resource equivalent to 0.25 annual workers was required to administer the system of choice (Finspångs kommun, 2018). In the municipality of Osby, four citizens had chosen the only approved private provider and the abolition of LOV was estimated to save 250,000 Swedish krona (SEK) annually (Sveriges Radio, 2018). In a decision protocol of the municipality of Vingåker, the same thing was described: “It has been the case throughout the years that the municipality of Vingåker has had more private providers approved than there have been users who have chosen private providers” (Vingåkers kommun, 2018). A social-democratic politician in the municipality of Vindeln says: “No one [of the older citizens] wants private home-care services, and instead we can transfer the resources that LOV requires to other activities” (Västerbottens-Kuriren, 2015).

In the municipality of Båstad, the abolition of LOV is justified by the fact that the previous private providers had very few users and there were currently no private providers left in the municipality. The local party Bjärepartiet argues that by abolishing LOV, the burden on the administration is reduced:

The introduction of LOV has taken a lot of administrative effort for a pressured administration with contracts of around 40 pages. The contracts must be followed up from a quality point of view and involve supervision that is often not done (Helsingborgs Dagblad, 2015).

In the municipality of Robertsfors, it is stated that the only private provider showed shortcomings during contract follow-ups, concerning, for example, time registration, routines and deviation reports. This along with the costs of maintaining LOV led the municipality to abolish LOV (Sveriges Radio, 2015).

The situation is different in the larger and often more centrally located municipalities. For example, in the municipality of Södertälje, a large municipality in the capital area with many different providers, arguments are put forward based on experiences of cancelled contracts, cheating and even police raids, which according to the Social Democrats demanded a large and expanding administrative apparatus for supervision: “With sixteen or more companies, based on the experiences we now have, at least ten more [administrative] positions are needed” (LT, 2014). A problem described is that in LOV, the municipality cannot restrict the number of private providers. The municipality of Sollentuna, also in the capital area, had similar problems with 15–20 different home-care providers. After suspending many contractors due to cheating and fraud, the municipality decided to abolish LOV (Mitt-i-Stockholm, 2022). Linköping, a large town, also describes a situation with providers' withdrawn permissions, terminated contracts and fraud: “Cheating is widespread, and the system requires large costs for the municipality” (Corren, 2020).

Several municipalities state problems with a lack of stability. For example, contracts may be terminated due to misconduct, or providers resign or go bankrupt. If so, the municipality must be prepared to assume responsibility for providing the granted care, but there are also problems with continuity for the users. For example, in the municipality of Värmdö, it is stated that the continual withdrawal or bankruptcy of private providers has created problems for both the municipality and the citizens: “… it has meant a burden on the whole organization and as a result, many homecare recipients have had to change providers” (Värmdö Kommun, 2020).

After LOV – then what?

When a municipality decides to abolish LOV, there is already a strategy of action for how to provide home-care services in the future. Usually, this strategy is the result of an investigation conducted by the municipal administration. There are two plausible replacements:

  1. Delivering homecare only by the public provider, i.e., a public monopoly.

  2. Procuring homecare according to the LOU – either all homecare in the municipality or a specified share of it, i.e., continued privatization.

In our investigation, the first outcome is the most common as presented in Table 4.

As shown above, a common argument to abolish LOV is that few citizens have chosen private providers or that there are not even any private providers, most likely because these municipalities are not lucrative enough for private companies. In all these cases, LOV has been replaced by a public monopoly meaning that when LOV is abolished, the municipality will reintroduce the system that was applied before LOV. Consequently, in the future, all home-care services will be carried out only by the public provider.

However, in another group of municipalities, the situation is different: There have been too many private providers and several reported cases of cheating and fraud. This group includes the large municipalities of Sollentuna, Södertälje and Linköping. In these cases, LOV is instead replaced by another procurement model – LOU. In LOU, a public procurement made by the municipality's administration determines which companies get the contracts. The evaluation of the companies is based on quality. In these cases, the economic compensation is fixed and regulated by the municipality, regardless of the provider.

In for example Sollentuna, the municipality has signed a contract with six home-care providers for three years. The municipally owned corporation Solom had to submit their tender in the procurement just like the private companies (Sollentuna kommun, 2022). In Södertälje, originally 40% of the total number of home-care hours were procured and shared between five private providers with fixed shares. The homecare is procured every four years and in the most recent round (2022) it was not possible to fill all the procured shares. As a result, the municipality now have a 67% share (LT, 2022). Citizens in Sollentuna and Södertälje still have a choice since a provider is selectable until it reaches its capacity ceiling by the procurement.

Linköping have chosen another model – LOU without user choice. More precisely, the municipality is divided into six geographical areas with one provider responsible for all users in each area: The public provider is responsible in three areas and private providers in the other three (Linköping kommun, 2023). Värmdö, an archipelago municipality close to the capital, has introduced a similar model with four geographical areas (Värmdö kommun, 2022). The municipality of Strängnäs will implement LOU with geographical areas in 2025. This decision was explained as follows: “By assigning providers of homecare based on geographic area, better conditions are provided for planning, coordination, scheduling, and reduced administration” (Strängnäs kommun, 2023). In these three municipalities, marketization remains with both private and public providers, but the citizen is assigned a provider by residential address and not by user choice.

In sum, we detect the following pattern: When LOV is abolished in smaller municipalities because of a weak position of private providers; it is replaced by public monopoly, i.e., an obvious case of re-municipalization. However, in larger municipalities, where the reason rather is misconduct or a high turnover by private providers (which also are too many) as well as high administrative costs, LOV is replaced by LOU. The latter implies a continued privatization with a mix of different providers, both private and public. An important difference is that the municipality has significantly more control in LOU since it is the municipality that decides upon the number of providers and their distribution, not the market.

Concluding discussion

The findings of the present study demonstrate that political arguments seem to have a very limited significance in abolishing LOV in Swedish home-care services, despite the party-dominated municipalities. The most frequent reasons found in the materials were instead pragmatic. This result supports previous research on re-municipalization showing that ideology can indeed be an important driver in privatization but largely lacks significance in re-municipalization (e.g., Jansson et al., 2021; see Hung and Lu, 2022). It means that drivers of re-municipalization in this case of social services do not deviate from technical services as have been suggested by other scholars (e.g., Petersen et al., 2015; Gradus and Budding, 2020; Jordahl and Persson, 2021) – it is a matter of pragmatism anyway.

Our empirical investigation included 20 Swedish municipalities and we discovered different patterns. In smaller municipalities, there were few private providers of homecare, with few users. The most frequent arguments for abolishing LOV were the weak position of private providers and the administrative burden. In smaller municipalities, LOV was replaced by a public monopoly. In the larger municipalities, there was a high turnover or even an experienced uncontrollable quantity of private providers and in some cases also reports of fraud and inadequate routines. The most frequent argument of larger municipalities was also the administrative burden, but in this case for control and review. In larger municipalities, LOV was replaced by another type of procurement – LOU.

The latter implies that a decision to abolish LOV does not necessarily imply a return to a public monopoly. When LOV is replaced by LOU, the model with different providers continues through another legal framework. It might have implications for the discussion on the concept of re-municipalization. Re-municipalization refers to a transfer from the municipality as a provider to the private sector, and then back to the municipality again (e.g., Voorn, 2021; Clifton et al., 2021). This is not a feasible description of the development in all the Swedish municipalities. Thus, decisions to abandon LOV cannot be said to represent a clear-cut case of re-municipalization.

Our findings raise the question of whether the concept of re-municipalization is too narrow. In LOV, the municipality's control is limited. LOV, a choice system with freedom of establishment, hands over the power to the market to decide the number of providers and their share since it is decided by the citizens' choices and the private companies' interests to apply. Consequently, a transition from LOV to LOU implies a development from the market's control of the distribution between providers to the municipality's control of the distribution. In LOU, the municipality decides the exact number of providers and often also the market share of each provider.

The transition to LOU is not covered by the current definition of re-municipalization. Hence, the concept fails to quite capture important aspects of how marketization at the local level may change and develop over time and in different ways in different local contexts. A suggestion is broadening the concept to include more dimensions. In its current form, re-municipalization is restricted to the provision of public services. It could be developed to also cover the control of public services. Such a broadening of the concept with both provision and control dimensions would be valuable in exploring and seeking to understand the next chapter of marketization at the local level in different countries.

We emphasize two limitations. Firstly, due to feasibility, our investigation was limited to the abolition of LOV in home-care services, with neither nursing homes nor the abolition of LOU included. Thus, generalization to Swedish eldercare overall should be cautiously done. Secondly, our empirical materials consist of secondary sources in the form of texts. While there are several advantages to such contemporary sources, the materials vary in length and detail between municipalities which may result in individual arguments for specific municipalities being missing. Interviews or surveys would have allowed us to ask more precise questions systematically but may have been affected by the time gap. We encourage future studies to further investigate the adoption and abolition of both LOV and LOU in all areas of Swedish eldercare using different methodological approaches.

Figures

Development of the act on system of choice (LOV) in Swedish municipalities

Figure 1

Development of the act on system of choice (LOV) in Swedish municipalities

Analytical framework for detecting arguments for abolishing LOV

ReasonsIndicators
Political reasons
Against profitsIdeological statements against for-profit providers in public welfare
For universalismIdeological statements for uniform services to the users
Pragmatic reasons
Weak position of private providersFew, if any, private alternatives and/or a low share of elderly choosing private providers
Lack of stability and controlThe number of private providers, their number of users and their durability cannot be controlled
Elder abuseMisconduct among private providers with reported cases of elder abuse and neglect
FraudMisconduct among private providers with reported cases of fraud
Inadequate routinesMisconduct among private providers with reported cases of inadequate routines
Administrative burdenAdministrative burden in a system of choice, for example concerning monitoring and tendering document

Source(s): Own creation

Analytical framework for analysing what happens after LOV

A return to the municipality?Indicators
ProvisionFrom a (possible) “welfare mix” with different types of providers to a monopoly of the public provider, i.e., all forms of privatization are abolished
ControlFrom the market's control of the distribution between providers to the municipality's control of the distribution, i.e., LOV is replaced by LOU

Source(s): Own creation

Arguments for abolishing LOV (findings in the empirical materials)

Developments after LOV (findings in the empirical materials)

Municipalities that have abolished LOV in home-care services

MunicipalityYear of adoption LOV in home careYear of abolition LOV in home careDecision-making body, date for decision, paragraph in protocol
Båstad20142016Decision by the municipal council 2016–04–27, § 75
Eslöv20112021Missing data
Fagersta20102014Decision by the municipal council 2014–02–25, § 4
Finspång20102018Decision by the municipal council 2018–02–28, § 23
Hjo20102017Decision by the municipal council 2017–04–27, § 39
Hässleholm20102016Decision by the municipal council 2016–05–09, § 73
Kristinehamn20102011Decision by the care committee (socialnämnden) 2011–01–19, § 16
Linköping20102020Decision by the municipal council 2020–08–25, § 171
Mullsjö20122022Missing data
Munkedal20102022Decision by the municipal council 2023–02–27, § 9
Nordanstig20102022Decision by the municipal council 2022–02–28, § 9
Osby20102018Decision by the municipal council 2018–02–26, § 11
Robertsfors20102015Decision by the municipal council 2015–09–21, § 55
Rättvik20102018Decision by the municipal council 2018–12–13, § 96
Skurup20112016Missing data
Sollentuna20092022Decision by the municipal council 2022–04–21, § 40
Strängnäs20122022Decision by the municipal council 2022–03–28, § 39
Svalöv20112019Decision by the municipal council 2019–12–16, § 246
Södertälje20102014Decision by the municipal council 2014–02–02, § 6
Tjörn20102017Decision by the care committee (socialnämnden) 2017–11–15, § 206
Vindeln20102015Decision by the municipal council 2015–11–16, § 97
Vingåker20102020Decision by the municipal council 2020–04–20, § 34
Värmdö20092020Decision by the municipal council 2020–10–07, § 167

Note(s): “Missing data” – it is proven that the municipality has applied LOV in home-care services and that LOV is no longer in use in home-care services, but it has not been possible to obtain decision protocols or other material describing the abolition. In these cases, the year of abolition is according to information obtained from SKR. These cases have not been included in the analysis

Year of adoption: Information is obtained from SKR, ”Kommuner och tjänster med LOV 1 juli 2020” (Xls-file)

Notes

1.

“Home-care services” involve individually adapted interventions in the older citizen's own home regarding personal care and services.

2.

In most municipalities, a political decision to abolish user choice according to LOV is first taken by the care committee, then by the executive committee and finally by the popularly elected municipal council.

3.

These three municipalities are Eslöv, Mullsjö and Skurup.

4.

All 23 municipalities are listed in the supplemental file, “Municipalities that have abolished LOV in home-care services.”

5.

The quotations in the empirical parts of this article are translated from Swedish to English by the authors.

Supplemental file

Table A1

References

Albalate, D., Bel, G. and Reeves, E. (2021), “Government choice between contract termination and contract expiration in re-municipalization: a case of historical recurrence?”, International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 87 No. 3, pp. 461-479, doi: 10.1177/00208523211002608.

Albalate, D., Bel, G. and Reeves, E. (2022), “Are we there yet? Understanding the implementation of re-municipalization decisions and their duration”, Public Management Review, Vol. 24 No. 6, pp. 951-974, doi: 10.1080/14719037.2021.1877795.

Ascoli, U. and Ranci, C. (2002), Dilemmas of the Welfare Mix, Kluwer Academic, New York.

Bel, G., Hebdon, R. and Warner, M. (2018), “Beyond privatisation and cost savings: alternatives for local government reform”, Local Government Studies, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 73-182, doi: 10.1080/03003930.2018.1428190.

Berlin, J., Jansson, M., Karlsson, D. and Carlström, E. (2022), “Involuntary backsourcing in the public sector: from conflict to collaboration”, Public Administration, Vol. 100 No. 3, pp. 674-691, doi: 10.1111/padm.12740.

Berlin, J., Carlström, E. and Karlsson, D. (2023), “Backsourcing in the private and public sectors. A systematic review”, Financial Accountability & Management, Vol. 00 No. 3, pp. 1-52, doi: 10.1111/faam.12361.

Blix, M. and Jordahl, H. (2021), Privatizing Welfare Services. Lessons from the Swedish Experiment, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Blomqvist, P. and Winblad, U. (2022), “Contracting out welfare services: how are private contractors held accountable?”, Public Management Review, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 233-254, doi: 10.1080/14719037.2020.1817530.

Bönker, F., Libbe, J. and Wollmann, H. (2016), “Remunicipalisation revisited: long-term trends in the provision of local public services in Germany”, Wollmann, H., Koprić, I. and Marcou, G. (Ed. s), Public and Social Services in Europe: from Public and Municipal to Private Sector Provision, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 71-85.

Bretzer, Y.N., Persson, B. and Barfoed Randrup, T. (2016), “Is public procurement efficiency conditioned by market types? A critical test in park and road sectors in Sweden”, International Journal of Public Sector Management, Vol. 29 No. 5, pp. 488-501, doi: 10.1108/IJPSM-02-2016-0039.

Carlström, E., Jansson, M., Karlsson, D. and Berlin, J. (2023), “Quasi-backsourcing in the public sector – the challenge of withdrawing from an intertwined and long-standing relationship”, International Journal of Public Administration, Vol. 46 No. 4, pp. 302-311, doi: 10.1080/01900692.2021.1995411.

Clifton, J., Warner, M., Gradus, R. and Bel, G. (2021), “Re-municipalization of public services: trend or hype?”, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 293-304, doi: 10.1080/17487870.2019.1691344.

Corren (2020), “S vill avveckla valfrihetssystemet”, 29 January, p. 10.

Dagens Samhälle (2021), “Därför vill M skrota valfriheten i hemtjänsten”, 29 October.

Damanpour, F., Magelssen, C. and Walker, R.M. (2020), “Outsourcing and insourcing of organizational activities: the role of outsourcing process mechanisms”, Public Management Review, Vol. 22 No. 6, pp. 767-790, doi: 10.1080/14719037.2019.1601243.

Elinder, M. and Jordahl, H. (2013a), “Political preferences and public sector outsourcing”, European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 30, pp. 43-57, doi: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2013.01.003.

Elinder, M. and Jordahl, H. (2013b), “Kontrakt, kostnader och kvalitet”, in Jordahl, H. (Ed.), Välfärdstjänster I Privat Regi: Framväxt Och Drivkrafter, SNS Förlag, Stockholm, pp. 89-120.

Feltenius, D. (2017), “Towards a more diversified supply of welfare services? Marketisation and the local governing of nursing homes in the scandinavian countries”, Sivesind, K.H. and Saglie, J. (Ed. s), Promoting Active Citizenship: Markets and Choice in Scandinavian Welfare, Palgrave Macmillan, Cham, Switzerland, pp. 111-157.

Feltenius, D. and Wide, J. (2019), “Business as usual? Civil society organizations in a marketized Swedish welfare state”, Journal of Civil Society, Vol. 15 No. 3, pp. 230-248, doi: 10.1080/17448689.2019.1623452.

Feltenius, D. and Wide, J. (2023), “Conservation or disappearance? The public provider of home care services in a system of choice”, Public Management Review, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 63-83, doi: 10.1080/14719037.2021.1937685.

Finspångs kommun (2018), “Kommunfullmäktige. Sammanträdesprotokoll. 2018-02-28”, Decision protocol, Finspång municipality, Finspång.

Göteborgs-Posten (2018), “Ingen valfrihet i hemtjänsten”, 13 January, p. 18.

Government Bill (2008), Lagen om valfrihetssystem, Prop. 2008/09:29.

Gradus, R. and Budding, T. (2020), “Political and institutional explanations for increasing re-municipalization”, Urban Affairs Review, Vol. 56 No. 2, pp. 538-564, doi: 10.1177/1078087418787907.

Guo, M. and Willner, S. (2017), “Swedish politicians' preferences regarding the privatisation of elderly care”, Local Government Studies, Vol. 43 No. 1, pp. 1-21, doi: 10.1080/03003930.2016.1237354.

Hall, D. (2012), Re-municipalising municipal services in Europe, A report commissioned by EPSU to PublicServices International Research Unit (PSIRU), London.

Hall, D., Lobina, E. and Terhorst, P. (2013), “Re-municipalisation in the early twenty-first century: water in France and energy in Germany”, International Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 193-214, doi: 10.1080/02692171.2012.754844.

Hanna, T.M. and McDonald, D.A. (2021), “From pragmatic to politicized? The future of water remunicipalization in the United States”, Utilities Policy, Vol. 72, 101276, doi: 10.1016/j.jup.2021.101276.

Hardell, S., Johansson Sevä, I. and Öun, I. (2020), “Welfare service privatization and opinions about service quality: the role of political ideology among local politicians and the public”, Social Policy Administration, Vol. 54 No. 1, pp. 45-59, doi: 10.1111/spol.12509.

Hefetz, A. and Warner, M. (2004), “Privatization and its reverse: explaining the dynamics of the government contracting process”, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 171-190, doi: 10.1093/jopart/muh012.

Nordvästra Skånes Tidningar (2015), “Därför vill Bjärepartiet avveckla LOV”, 5 November, p. 5.

Nordvästra Skånes Tidningar (2016), “Fullmäktige fällde LOV – till sist”, 29 April, p. 4.

Hung, W.-J. and Lu, J. (2022), “What brings the state back in? An examination of contracting reversal”, International Journal of Public Sector Management, Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 441-462, doi: 10.1108/IJPSM-06-2021-0159.

Jansson, M., Carlström, E., Karlsson, D. and Berlin, J. (2021), “Drivers of outsourcing and backsourcing in the public sector—from idealism to pragmatism”, Financial Accountability and Management, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 262-278, doi: 10.1111/faam.12273.

Jordahl, H. and Persson, L. (2021), “The end of a trend: retraction of choice in Swedish elderly care”, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 189-200, doi: 10.1080/17487870.2020.1746660.

Klingberg Hjort, M. and Martinsson, K. (2021), Hemtjänstmaffian. Miljonsvindeln Som Förändrade Äldreomsorgen, Bokförlaget Atlas, Stockholm.

Lidström, A. (2012), “Sweden: party‐dominated subnational democracy under challenge?”, Hendriks, F., Lidström, A. and Loughlin, J. (Ed. s), The Oxford Handbook of Local and Regional Democracy in Europe, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 261-281.

Lindh, A. and Johansson Sevä, I. (2018), “Political partisanship and welfare service privatization: ideological attitudes among local politicians in Sweden”, Scandinavian Political Studies, Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 75-97, doi: 10.1111/1467-9477.12109.

Lindmark, T., Ingard, C. and Trygged, S. (2023), “Prerequisites for empowerment: a study of procurement documents for the provision of care in Swedish nursing homes”, European Journal of Social Work, Vol. 26 No. 5, pp. 853-868, doi: 10.1080/13691457.2022.2115017.

Linköping kommun (2023), “Områdesbaserad vård och omsorg i hemmet”, Published, available at: https://www.linkoping.se/omsorg-och-hjalp/aldre/omradesbaserad-vard-och-omsorg-i-hemmet/ (accessed at 4 September 2023).

LT (2014), “Trygg hemtjänst med ny modell för valfrihet”, 3 February, available at: https://www.lt.se/2014-02-03/trygg-hemtjanst-med-ny-modell-for-valfrihet (accessed 8 April 2022).

LT (2022), “Svårt att locka privata aktörer till hemtjänsten”, 1 December, p. 8.

Mitt-i-Sollentuna (2022), “LOV kan skrotas för att få bort fusket inom hemtjänsten”, 2 April, p. 5.

Moberg, L. (2017), “Marketisation of nordic eldercare – is the model still universal?”, Journal of Social Policy, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 603-621, doi: 10.1017/S0047279416000830.

Moberg, L. (2023), “User choice and the changing notion of social citizenship in Swedish elderly care”, Nordic Social Work Research, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 91-106, doi: 10.1080/2156857X.2021.1948443.

Moberg, L., Blomqvist, P. and Winblad, U. (2016), “User choice in Swedish eldercare – conditions for informed choice and enhanced service quality”, Journal of European Social Policy, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 281-295, doi: 10.1177/0958928716645076.

Montin, S. (2016), “Local government and the market. The case for public services and care for the elderly in Sweden”, Wollmann, H., Koprić, I. and Marcou, G. (Ed. s), Public and Social Services in Europe: from Public and Municipal to Private Sector Provision, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 87-101.

Norrköpings-Tidninga (2018), “LOV inom hemtjänst läggs ned”, 28 February, p. 21.

Nya Kristinehamns-Posten (2011), “Socialnämnden avslutar valfrihetssystemet LOV”, 23 April, p. 4.

Petersen, O.H., Houlberg, K. and Christensen, L.R. (2015), “Contracting out local services: a tale of technical and social services”, Public Administration Review, Vol. 75 No. 4, pp. 560-570, doi: 10.1111/puar.12367.

Segaard, S.B. and Saglie, J. (2017), “Education and elderly care in Denmark, Norway and Sweden: national policies and legal frameworks for private providers”, Sivesind, K.H. and Saglie, J. (Ed. s), Promoting Active Citizenship: Markets and Choice in Scandinavian Welfare, Palgrave Macmillan, Cham, pp. 75-115.

Skaraborgsbygden (2017), “Hjo skrotar valfrihet inom äldreomsorgen”, 21 April, p. 3.

SKR (2018), Kommunernas Valfrihetssystem – Beslutsläge Oktober 2018, Pdf-File, Stockholm.

SKR (2019), Köp Av Verksamhet 2019. Kommuner Och Regioner 2006-2018, SKR, Stockholm.

SKR (2020), Kommuner Och Tjänster Med LOV 1 Juli 2020, Xls-File, Stockholm.

SKR (2023a), “Utveckling av LOV i Sverige”, available at: http://www.skr.se (accessed 20 November 2023).

SKR (2023b), “Valfrihetssystem i kommuner, beslutsläget 2023”, available at: http://www.skr.se (accessed 20 November 2023).

Socialstyrelsen (2014), Avgifter Inom Äldreomsorgen. Kartläggning Och Analys Av Kommunernas Avgiftssystem, Socialstyrelsen, Stockholm.

Södertälje Kommun (2014), Sammanträdesprotokoll. Omsorgsnämnden. 2014-01-27, Decision protocol, Södertälje municipality, Södertälje.

Sollentuna Kommun (2022), “Här är våra sex utförare av hemtjänst”, Published, available at: https://www.sollentuna.se/uweb/utforarportalen/nyheter2/har-ar-vara-sex-utforare-av-hemtjanst/(accessed 28 October 2022).

Stolt, R. and Winblad, U. (2009), “Mechanisms behind privatization: a case study of private growth in Swedish elderly care”, Social Science and Medicine, Vol. 68 No. 5, pp. 903-911, doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2008.12.011.

Strängnäs Kommun (2023), “Förändringar inom hemtjänsten”, Published, available at: https://www.strangnas.se/omsorg-och-hjalp/hemtjanst/forandringar-inom-hemtjansten (accessed 12 April 2023).

Sveriges Radio (2015), “S i Robertsfors vill riva upp valfrihet i hemtjänsten”, 27 May, available at: https://sverigesradio.se/artikel/6174660 (accessed 8 April 2022).

Sveriges Radio (2018), “Osby – fjärde kommunen som avskaffar LOV”, 3 March, available at: https://sverigesradio.se/artikel/6897020 (accessed 8 April 2022).

Thakur-Wernz, P. (2019), “A typology of backsourcing: short-run total costs and internal capabilities for re-internalization”, Journal of Global Operations and Strategic Sourcing, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 42-61, doi: 10.1108/JGOSS-01-2018-0004.

Vabø, M. and Szebehely, M. (2012), “A caring state for older people?”, Anttonen, A., Häikiö, L. and Stefánsson, K. (Ed. s), Welfare State, Universialism and Diversity, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 121-143.

Värmdö Kommun (2020), Upphandlingsstrategi för hemtjänsten i Värmdö Kommun, Tjänsteskrivelse, 2020KS/0897, Official report, Värmdö municipality, Värmdö.

Värmdö Kommun (2022), “Värmdö kommun upphandlar hemtjänst”, Published, available at: https://www.varmdo.se/foretagare/upphandling/hemtjanstprojektet (accessed 8 April 2022).

Västerbottens Folkblad (2012), “Obetänksam privatiseringsiver i Vindeln”, 3 May, p. 3.

Västerbottens Folkblad (2015), “Robertsfors skrotar valfrihet i hemtjänsten”, 27 May, available at: https://www.folkbladet.nu/2015-05-27/robertsfors-skrotar-valfrihet-i-hemtjansten (accessed 8 April 2022).

Västerbottens-Kuriren (2015), “LOV utreds mer i Vindeln”, 21 September, p. 13.

Vingåkers Kommun (2018), Sammanträdesprotokoll. Socialnämnden. 2018-10-22. Decision protocol, Vingåker municipality, Vingåker.

Voorn, B. (2021), “Country, sector and method effects in studying remunicipalization: a meta-analysis”, International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 87 No. 3, pp. 440-460, doi: 10.1177/00208523211007915.

Voorn, B., Genugten, M.L. and van Thiel, S. (2021), “Re-interpreting Re-municipalization: finding equilibrium”, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 305-318, doi: 10.1080/17487870.2019.1701455.

Warner, M. (2008), “Reversing privatization, rebalancing government reform: markets, deliberation and planning”, Policy and Society, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 163-174, doi: 10.1016/j.polsoc.2008.09.001.

Warner, M. (2023), “Pragmatic municipalism: privatization and remunicipalisation in the US”, Local Government Studies, Vol. ahead of print, Published online, pp. 1-19, Ahead of Print, Published online 04 Jan, doi: 10.1080/03003930.2022.2162884.

Warner, M. and Aldag, A. (2021), “Re-Municipalization in the us: a pragmatic response to contracting”, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 319-332, doi: 10.1080/17487870.2019.1646133.

Warner, M. and Hefetz, A. (2012), “Insourcing and outsourcing: the dynamics of privatization among U.S. Municipalities 2002-2007”, Journal of the American Planning Association, Vol. 78 No. 3, pp. 313-327, doi: 10.1080/01944363.2012.715552.

Wollmann, H. (2018), “Public and personal social services in European countries from public/municipal to private-and back to municipal and ‘third sector’ provision”, International Public Management Journal, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 413-431, doi: 10.1080/10967494.2018.1428255.

Young, S. and Macinati, M.S. (2012), “Health outsourcing/backsourcing: case studies in the Australian and Italian Health sector”, Public Management Review, Vol. 14 No. 6, pp. 771-794, doi: 10.1080/14719037.2011.642627.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the participants at the SWEPSA Annual Conference (Örebro, 2022) and the NORKOM Research Conference (Reykjavik, 2022) as well as three anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and constructive feedback. This work was financially supported by the Swedish Research Council for Health, Working Life and Welfare (FORTE) under grant [dnr 2018-00423].

Corresponding author

David Feltenius can be contacted at: david.feltenius@umu.se

Related articles