Economic sustainability of biogas production from animal manure: a regional circular economy model

Devrim Murat Yazan (Department of Industrial Engineering and Business Information Systems, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands)
Davide Cafagna (Department of Mechanics, Mathematics and Management, Politecnico di Bari, Bari, Italy and Department of Industrial Engineering and Business Information Systems, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands)
Luca Fraccascia (Department of Industrial Engineering and Business Information Systems, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands)
Martijn Mes (Department of Industrial Engineering and Business Information Systems, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands)
Pierpaolo Pontrandolfo (Department of Mechanics, Mathematics and Management, Politecnico di Bari, Bari, Italy)
Henk Zijm (Department of Industrial Engineering and Business Information Systems, Universiteit Twente, Enschede, The Netherlands)

Management Research Review

ISSN: 2040-8269

Article publication date: 10 April 2018

Issue publication date: 5 June 2018

7999

Abstract

Purpose

This paper aims to understand the implementation of a circular economic business where animal manure is used to produce biogas and alternative fertilizer in a regional network of manure suppliers and biogas producers and to reveal the impacts of five variables (manure quantity, transportation distance, manure dry content, manure price and manure discharge price) on the economic sustainability of manure-based biogas supply chains.

Design/methodology/approach

An enterprise input-output approach is used to model physical and monetary flows of the manure-based biogas supply chain. Computational experiments are performed on all variables to identify under which conditions the cooperation is beneficial for all actors.

Findings

The cooperation is profitable for a large-scale farm (>20,000 t/year) if biogas producer (b) pays farmer (f) to receive its manure (5 €/t) or if f sells manure for free and manure disposal costs are >10 €/t. Cooperation is always profitable for b if f pays b to supply its manure (5€/t). If b receives manure for free, benefits are always positive if b is a medium-large-scale plant (>20,000 t/year). For a small-scale plant, benefits are positive if manure dry content (MDC) is ≥12 per cent and transportation distance is ≤10 km.

Originality/value

The paper adds value to the biogas production research, as it makes holistic analysis of five variables which might change under different policy and geographical conditions. The investors in biogas production, suppliers and transportation companies can find correspondence to empirical findings for their own site-specific cases.

Keywords

Citation

Yazan, D.M., Cafagna, D., Fraccascia, L., Mes, M., Pontrandolfo, P. and Zijm, H. (2018), "Economic sustainability of biogas production from animal manure: a regional circular economy model", Management Research Review, Vol. 41 No. 5, pp. 605-624. https://doi.org/10.1108/MRR-02-2018-0053

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Devrim Murat Yazan, Davide Cafagna, Luca Fraccascia, Martijn Mes, Pierpaolo Pontrandolfo and Henk Zijm.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


Introduction

Since the industrial revolution, the world economy has followed a “take-make-consume and dispose” pattern of growth, a linear model based on the assumption that resources are abundantly available, easy to source and cheap to dispose of (European Commission, 2015). Such a model causes large environmental pressure on the planetary boundaries, because it is characterized by high consumption of raw materials, relatively high waste during production and waste discharge after production (Bruckner et al., 2012; Giljum et al., 2015; Wiedmann et al., 2015). Therefore, such models are not sustainable from the environmental point of view. In particular, the increasing awareness that natural resources are limited pushes toward the development and the implementation of new circular economy models, able to manage existing resources in a continuous cycle, hence providing an effective use of these resources (Bocken et al., 2016; Fraccascia et al., 2016). In this regard, the European Commission claims that circular economy may be able to provide economic benefits for firms, in addition to environmental benefits, and widely recommends their adoption (European Commission, 2015).

Within this framework, an important issue concerns the energy production. As about 60 per cent of the total electric energy is produced from fossil fuels (International Energy Agency, 2014), energy generation is one of the main reasons of greenhouse gas emissions (Soytas et al., 2007). Such emissions are widely recognized as the main driver of climate change (IPCC, 2014). With the aim to mitigate this problem, alternative technologies have been developed to produce energy from renewable resources. A well-known example is the production of energy from second-generation biomass (McKendry, 2002; Albino et al., 2015). While first-generation biomass refers to organic products that principally were used to produce food, whose use generated a large ethical debate, second-generation biomass refers to organic secondary outputs, e.g. solid and liquid municipal wastes, manure, lumber and pulp mill wastes and forest and agricultural residues (Hall and House, 1994; Miyamoto, 1997). Therefore, the use of second-generation biomass is widely promoted in bioenergy production (International Energy Agency, 2008; Ellen Macarthur Foundation, 2013).

In particular, the use of manure for energy production may offer remarkable opportunities at places where intensive livestock farming is practiced (Massaro et al., 2015). Technologically speaking, manure-based bioenergy can be produced in two different ways:

  1. producing biogas by anaerobic digestion (AD); and

  2. producing biochar, bio-oil and gases through pyrolysis (P) (Beardmore, 2011; Guo et al., 2013).

In both cases, the resulting products can be used as fuel to generate electric energy. Currently, AD ensures the highest performance from both an environmental and an economic point of view (Appels et al., 2011; Miller and Moyle, 2014).

As in The Netherlands, intensive livestock farming is practiced, the amount of manure produced is considerable and its exploitation for bioenergy production may have a remarkable potential. However, the possibility to produce manure-based energy is actually not fully exploited because of some obstacles in the cooperation among manure producers and biogas producers (De Korte, 2012). Therefore, designing and organizing biogas supply chains (BGSCs) becomes more difficult. As a consequence, the potential environmental and economic benefits cannot be achieved.

This paper analyzes the manure-based BGSC, i.e. biogas production from manure by AD. Through a case example, this paper aims at identifying the main variables affecting the cooperation dynamics among manure producers and biogas producers. To this end, we model the manure-based BGSC through the enterprise input-output (EIO) approach, modeling physical and monetary flows into the supply chain and assessing the environmental and economic benefits generated. Then, we use numerical analysis via computational experiments to assess the impacts of five variables (manure quantity, transportation distance, manure dry content, manure price and manure discharge price) on the supplier–buyer relationships in the local markets to foster cooperation and to stimulate the production of renewable energy. Besides, our work provides practical and managerial contributions aimed at enhancing the development of circular economy models on a local level.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the generic EIO model for supply chains, followed by addressing EIO model application in a case example. Then, the circular business model is presented, and a scenario analysis is proposed to reveal the role of uncertainty on cooperation decisions. Results of the computational experiments are presented and discussed. Finally, the paper ends with conclusions.

Enterprise input-output model for supply chains

In this section, we use a physical EIO model to quantify the material/energy/waste flows of the BGSC and integrate it into the monetary EIO model to calculate the economic performance of the BGSC. The generic EIO model for supply chains is adopted from a paper by Yazan et al. (2011).

The functional unit of the supply chain is modeled as a process that transforms inputs into outputs and produces wastes from such a transformation. The process may require two kinds of inputs:

  1. primary inputs, which are purchased from outside the supply chain; and

  2. main inputs, which come from other processes belonging to the supply chain (outputs produced by other processes).

Each process can require more than one input and generate more than one waste. However, for the sake of simplicity, we suppose that each process can produce only one output (which means that the term “output” in the sequel may refer both to the main product and the process producing that product). Figure 1 displays a simple representation of a supply chain process from an input-output perspective.

Let us consider a supply chain composed of n processes. We define Z0 as the matrix of domestic intermediate deliveries between processes, f0 as the vector of final demands and x0 as the vector of gross outputs. The matrix Z0 is of size n × n, and both vectors f0 and x0 are of size n × 1. The intermediate coefficients matrix A is defined as follows:

(1) A=Z0x^01

Here, x̂0 denotes the diagonal matrix so that x̂0ii = x0i ∀ i and all the other elements are equal to zero. The generic element of the intermediate coefficients matrix Aij denotes the necessary quantity of input i to produce one unit of output j. Therefore, we have (note that the spectral radius of the non-negative matrix A is smaller than one):

(2) x0=Ax0+f0=(IA)1f0

Besides, there are s primary inputs purchased from outside the supply chain, and m by-products and wastes are produced as secondary outputs within the supply chain. Let r0 be the primary input vector (size s × 1) and w0 be the by-product/waste vector (m × 1). Let R be the s × n matrix of primary input coefficients, with the element Rkj denoting the use of primary input k (1,…, s) per unit of output of process j, and let W be the m × n matrix of waste and by-product coefficients, with the element Wlj denoting the output of by-product or waste type l (1,…, m) per unit of output of process j. It results:

(3) r0=Rx0
(4) w0=Wx0

To describe the monetary EIO model, we first introduce the unitary cost and price vectors; p0 is the vector (n × 1) of the prices, with the element p0i indicating the unitary price of the main product of process i. Therefore, using the vector of gross outputs x0, we can calculate the vector y0 (n × 1), representing the total revenues associated with each gross output as follows:

(5) y0=x^0p0

Furthermore, we can determine the monetary coefficients matrix B (n × n), with the generic element Bij expressed as:

(6) Bij=Aijp0ip0j

Then, we can determine b0 as follows:

(7) b0=By0+f^0p0=(IB)1f^0p0

Here, f̂0 denotes the diagonal matrix so that f̂0ii = f0i ∀ i and all the other elements are equal to zero. Moreover, we define the vector of prices (or costs) p0w (m × 1), where the generic element p0iw represents the unitary price (or cost) associated with the by-products (or wastes) in all processes (i.e. by-products represent economic gains and waste represents treatment costs). Hence, using the matrix W, we can identify the vector y0w, a n × 1 vector, representing the total revenues associated with all by-products and wastes for each process as follows:

(8) y0w=[(p0w)TWx^0]T

In addition, let p0r (s × 1) be the unitary primary input prices vector. Then, we can compute y0r (n × 1), the vector of the costs associated to each process for the primary inputs purchasing (including workforce).

(9) y0r=[(p0r)TRx^0]T

The vector of intermediate inputs costs y0z (n × 1) is also calculated using p0 and i (n × 1 unit vector, having all elements equal to one).

(10) y0z=[(i)Tp^0Ax^0]T

Finally, we introduce d0, which is a n × 1 vector representing the amortization costs. The generic element d0i represents the annual amortization cost of process i. Then, the profit of the whole production chain (П) can be computed as:

(11) Π=i=1n(yi+yiwyizyirdi)

The model serves as a planning and accounting tool for the involved supply chain actors, and its use is demonstrated in the next section for a manure-based BGSC.

The manure-based biogas supply chain: a case example

In this section, we assess the manure-based BGSC by adopting the EIO approach. The main production processes within the manure-based BGSC are presented in Figure 2. Manure is collected from farms, loaded into trucks and transported to the biogas plant. Then, manure is mixed with other types of biomass to increase biogas yield in later stages. In this paper, we assume the use of corn silage for the mixing process. The obtained blend is converted into biogas and digestate (a nutrient-rich material remaining after AD) by means of AD, where microorganisms break down the biodegradable material in the absence of oxygen. Afterwards, biogas is used for combined heat and power generation for the production of electricity and heat (American Biogas Council, 2014).

Accordingly, five main processes are considered: manure collection (P1), transportation (P2), mixing (P3), AD (P4) and combustion (P5). Each process receives a main input and produces a main output. All these outputs are physical products, except for the output of the transportation process, which is the distance covered between the manure producer and the biogas producer. There are also four primary inputs (gasoil, workforce, electricity and other biomass), four wastes (CO2, N2O, CH4 and NH3) and three by-products sold as a value-added (solid digestate, liquid digestate and heat).

In this section, we apply the EIO model to a numerical case example by assuming fix costs and prices for a small-scale biogas plant, i.e. a plant able to receive in input up to 5,000 t of manure per year. All values are referred to a time range of one year. The computations of this section are the basis of the next section, where we describe the circular business model scenario and apply computational experiments to reveal the role of the above-mentioned five variables on chains’ economic performance.

In the base scenario, we assume 5,000 t/year of cattle manure and an average transportation distance of 3 km between the farm and the small-scale biogas plant. Values of technical parameters are extracted from some previous studies in the literature (Navaratnasamy et al., 2008; Amon et al., 2007; El-Mashad and Zhang, 2010). In particular, we assume that the manure is characterized by 12 per cent of dry content and 85 per cent of organic content, and we assume a mixture rate of 98 per cent manure and 2 per cent corn silage. The volatile solid content of dry matter of manure has an average value of 80 per cent, while the percentage of volatile solid in the whole manure is 16 per cent (Al Seadi et al., 2013). Furthermore, we assume that 0.8 t of digestate can be produced by 1 t of manure (Berglund and Borjesson, 2006). Finally, we assume that the cogeneration process can produce 1.7 kWh of electricity and 7.7 MJ of heat from the exploitation of 1 m3of biogas (Navaratnasamy et al., 2008). Methane production from manure processing is 0.2 m3/kg of volatile solid content (Al Seadi et al., 2013).

In cogeneration, biogas passes through a gasometer and after the heat exchanger process, heat and exhaust gas are emitted. In the meanwhile, electricity is produced and also reused within the cogeneration plant. Figures 3 and 4 present the physical and monetary input-output tables, respectively. Physical input-output table (Figure 3) shows final output production, primary input consumption and waste generation by each process depicted in Figure 2, as well as the physical exchanges among processes. Figure 4, on the other hand, displays the costs and benefits associated with physical flows of the manure-based BGSC. We assume that the electricity generation unit uses four-stroke engine with an electrical efficiency of 35-40 per cent (Deublein and Steinhauser, 2008).

Figure 3 shows that in the base scenario, the plant produces 192 t of CO2, 612 t of solid digestate, 3,468 t of liquid digestate, 315,783 KWh of heat and 251,090 KWh of electricity per year. We apply 10 per cent mark-up for the final products of the bio-energy plant, while the manure, gasoil and corn silage prices are considered fixed on 2 €/t, 1.2 €/liter and 40 €/t respectively. As the literature shows that economic value of digestate ranges from 0.5 to 3.2 €/t (Lantz, 2012), we assume an average price of 1.85 €/t digestate. According to Navaratnasamy et al. (2008), the capital cost of a small-sized biogas plant is 6,510 €/KWh, and the running cost is 0.019 €/KWh. Furthermore, government incentives for renewable energy production are 0.056 €/KWh in The Netherlands (International Energy Agency, 2014). From Figure 4, it can be seen that the chain produces a total annual value-added of 84 K€ with a loss of 58 K€ and employment of 142 K€ in the base scenario, where value-added is measured as the sum of profit and wages. The loss is due to the difference between total costs and benefits, while value added is positive, as it is the sum of the (negative) profit and wages. We understand from the base scenario that small-scale cattle manure-based biogas plant is not profitable. We show in section 4 that the medium-big-scale biogas plants can be profitable under certain conditions.

As we can see from Figure 4, there is no economic convenience under the conditions provided for the small-scale biogas plant’s supply chain. However, economies of scale and the other variables such as existing manure discharge cost or manure price might provide additional economic benefit to the supply chain’s profit. Therefore, in the next section, we apply our model to medium- and large-scale biogas plants.

Circular business model scenario

By adopting circular economy models, the produced wastes can be exploited as new production inputs instead of being disposed of in the landfill. In such a way, the consumption of natural resources is reduced, in addition to the lower amount of wastes landfilled, and the circularity is achieved.

As bioenergy supplier and buyer networks are characterized by a notable level of uncertainty (Yazan et al., 2012), our next step is associated with revealing the role of variables that influence the chain performance. Accordingly, decisions-to-cooperate of BGSC actors will change. We consider two actors in the manure-based BGSC: a farmer (f) and a bioenergy producer (b). As an addition to the base scenario, we assume that the farmer is also a cultivator, meaning that the digestate produced by the bioenergy producer can be used by the farmer in cultivation of sunflowers. Figure 5 displays the simple input/output flows of such a circular business model.

We evaluate two scenarios: non-cooperation and cooperation. In the former, the farmer produces manure which is used as fertilizer for sunflower cultivation, and the biogas plant is not part of the business. In the cooperation scenario, the farmer produces manure which is sent to the biogas plant. The biogas plant produces biogas (used for electricity and heat production) and digestate, which is sold to the farmer. The farmer uses digestate as fertilizer for sunflower production. Therefore, local farmers are confronted with a decision to be involved in energy production.

In traditional production systems, farmers are not involved in energy production because they are mainly concerned with livestock farming. There are other feedstocks that can be used in biogas production instead of manure. Then, what motivates both actors to cooperate?

First, from an economic perspective, intensive livestock farming results in high quantity of manure, which exceeds the manure-based fertilizer demand (De Korte, 2012). Second, regulatory constraints on manure use as a substitute of fertilizer allows farmers only to use/sell limited amounts of manure (De Korte, 2012). Both situations influence the economic performance of farmers, leading to high manure disposal costs. The bioenergy producer, on the other hand, would have the advantage of producing a by-product to gain higher value-added, i.e. digestate.

From an operational perspective, the ammonia within digestate, differently from nitrogen in raw manure, is immediately absorbed by the soil. In this way, it directly contributes to plant growth. Digestate has three other remarkable advantages for the agricultural practice:

  1. It does not present the odor nuisance, providing increased land application options.

  2. It makes weed control easier and more efficient for farmers by destroying unwanted weeds.

  3. It is more homogeneous, which makes fertilizer spreading more uniform.

Let us present the benefits from cooperation versus non-cooperation. The subscript f refers to the farm, b to the bioenergy producer. The superscripts (0) and (1) indicate the scenario of no cooperation and cooperation, respectively.

For the farmer, the benefit from cooperation is given by:

(12) Bf=Rf(1)Rf(0)
where:

Bf = farm benefits from cooperation.

Rf(0) = farm revenues in case of no cooperation.

Rf(1) = farm revenues in case of cooperation.

For the bioenergy producer, the benefit is given by:

(13) Bb=Rb(1)Rb(0)
where:

Bb = bioenergy producer benefits from cooperation.

Rb(0) = bioenergy producer revenues in case of no cooperation.

Rb(1) = bioenergy producer revenues in case of cooperation.

We assume that the bioenergy producer pays for manure transportation and the farmer pays for digestate transportation. Sunflower price and production costs remain constant in both scenarios. Production costs of the bioenergy producer are attributed to the operating costs (i.e. biogas production costs, digestate production costs, cost of mixing and heat production costs). We introduce Ci, Pi, Qi to denote the unitary cost of production, the unitary market price and the quantity produced of the i-th element, respectively; and E and H indicate the electricity and heat produced from bioenergy producer, respectively. Finally, Cddischarge is the unitary cost of manure discharge and Pdgovernment incentive is the incentive provided by government per unit biomass-based electricity production. Then, we can compute Rf(0) and Rf(1)as follows:

(14) Rf(0)=Pfsunflowers×Qsunflowers(0)Cfsunflowers×Qsunflowers(0)Cfdischarge×[Qproduced manure(0) Qused manure(0)]
(15) Rf(1)=Pfsunflowers×Qsunflowers(1)+Pfmanure(1)×Qmanure(1)Pfdigestate(1)×Qdigestate(1)Cdigestate transportation×Qdigestate(1) Cfsunflowers×Qsunflowers(1)

Rb(0) and Rb(1) can be calculated as:

(16) Rb(0)=0
(17) Rb(1)=Eproduced(1)×Pbelectricity+Hproduced(1)×Pbheat+Eproduced(1)×Pbgovernemnt incentive+Pbdigestate(1)×Qdigestate(1)Eproduced(1)×Cboperating(1)Pfmanure(1)×Qmanure(1)Ctransportation×Qmanure(1)Camortization(1)Cotherbiomasspurchase(1)

To understand how uncertainty affects cooperation among actors, we identify five operational, technical and economic variables (manure quantity, transportation distance, manure dry content, manure price and manure discharge price) and investigate their impact on the implementation of the supplier–buyer relationships in the local manure markets. We use three fixed values for each variable as follows:

  1. manure quantity (5,000, 20,000 and 100,000 t/year);

  2. transportation distance between farm and bioenergy plant (2, 10 and 30 km);

  3. manure dry content (8, 10 and 12 per cent) and organic matter content of manure (80, 82 and 85 per cent);

  4. manure price (−5, 0 and 5 €/t); and

  5. manure discharge cost (5, 10 and 15 €/t).

These variables have critical importance for operational efficiency and economic performance of the manure-based BGSC. Manure quantity is decisive on plant scale in the cooperation scenario, as well as on fertilizer use and discharge costs in the non-cooperation scenario. Transportation distance has a significant impact as the manure has a very low value, which is an obstacle for long-distance transportation. Manure dry content and organic matter contents are critical for the biogas and digestate yields. Manure discharge cost is also a critical variable, particularly when the bioenergy producer is a unique alternative to manure discharge. Accordingly, we assume that the biogas producer does not pay more than the discharge cost to the farmer in the cooperation-case. Concerning the manure price, −5 €/t indicates that farmer pays bioenergy producer to supply its manure, 0 €/t means that manure is sent to the bioenergy producer for free and 5 €/t refers to the case in which bioenergy producer pays farmer to receive its manure.

The amount of other biomass, i.e. corn silage, mixed with manure (2 per cent of the blend), the available cultivation land (1,000 ha) and manure application rate (10 t/ha) are assumed constant. Considering that biogas production from cattle manure was not profitable in our base scenario analysis (Figure 4), and swine manure has a higher biogas yield; we use swine manure data for our computational experiments.

Results and discussion

We apply computational experiments based on what-if scenarios. Considering three values for each variable, in total we obtain 35 = 243 different combinations. These combinations represent the effects of uncertainty characterizing cooperation dynamics. In this section, we show the most relevant results, some of which display combined effects of the variables.

Impact of manure quantity

According to Figure 6, manure quantity notably affects cooperation benefits. For a small- and medium-size farm (≤20,000 t/year of manure), the benefits are negative. For the bioenergy producer, the higher the scale, the higher the benefits from the cooperation will be, ceteris paribus.

Impact of manure price and manure quantity

Figure 7 shows the impact of manure price and quantity on actors’ benefits. When the farmer pays the bioenergy producer to supply its manure (manure price = −5 €/t), farm benefits are negative in case of small-medium scale (≤20,000 t/year of manure). In such a case, the benefits for the large-scale bioenergy producer are the highest. When the bioenergy producer pays the farmer for the manure (manure price = 5 €/t), the benefits for the bioenergy producer are negative in case of small-medium-size plant. The large-scale farmer benefits the most.

Impact of manure dry content and manure quantity

Figure 8 displays the impact of manure dry content (and organic content) on cooperation dynamics. Expectedly, if manure dry content is high, cooperation benefits increase.

Impact of transportation distance and manure quantity

According to Figure 9, the shorter the transportation distance, the greater the benefits arising from cooperation. The impact increases with increasing farm and plant scale.

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure quantity

Farm benefits are strongly dependent on manure discharge cost (Figure 10). If discharge costs are high, the farm revenues in case of non-cooperation decrease because the remaining amount of manure, not usable as fertilizer, has to be disposed of. On the other hand, the bioenergy producer is not affected by the discharge cost.

However, depending on the case, manure discharge costs might provide an idea to the bioenergy producer about the manure price to offer to the farmer. Our next analysis is based on the combined effects of manure discharge cost and manure price.

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure price on benefits

In Figure 11, we present the combined effect of manure discharge cost and price on cooperation dynamics for a big-scale plant, having revealed in precedent analyses that big-scale cooperation is more advantageous. The farm has the highest benefit when manure discharge cost is 15 €/t and manure price is 5 €/t (bioenergy producer pays farmer to receive its manure). Bioenergy producer’s benefit reaches a peak if manure price is −5 €/t (when he is paid by farmer to receive its manure), regardless of the discharge cost.

Summarizing (Figures 6 to 11), cooperation is not profitable for a small-medium-scale farm (≤20,000 t/year). It is profitable for a large-scale farm if b pays f to receive its manure (5 €/t), regardless of the values of other variables; or if f provides its manure for free and manure discharge costs are high (10-15 €/t); or if f pays b to supply its manure (5 €/t) and at the same time manure disposal costs are very high (15 €/t).

Cooperation is always profitable for a bioenergy producer if f pays b to supply its manure (5 €/t). If b receives manure for free, benefits from cooperation are always positive if b is a medium-large- scale plant (>10,000 t/year). On the other hand, (if manure is free) for a small-scale b, benefits are positive only if manure dry content is high (MDC = 12 per cent) and transportation distance is short (≤10 km). If b pays f to receive its manure (5 €/t), b benefits are always negative, except when manure quantity processed is ≥100,000 t/year (large-scale bioenergy plant), MDC = 12 per cent and transportation distance is very short (≤2 km). We notice that manure quantity and manure price have the strongest impact on cooperation dynamics, because they significantly affect the benefits for both actors.

These results allow us to better understand the potential of cooperation through supply chain actors in the context of developing a local circular economy business model, as it was explained in “Circular business model scenario” section. Indeed, our results show that such a mechanism provides an effective use of existing local resources, particularly when the quantity of supply is high and the bioenergy plant uses the advantage of economies of scale. Small- and medium-size plants can also be advantageous under certain conditions discussed above. Based on the results of our analysis, in some cases, cooperation can be beneficial for one actor while the other one has negative economic return. However, when the total benefit is still positive, then to foster cooperation, benefits could be shared between the two actors. How companies can implement benefit-sharing schemes should be further investigated in future research. Furthermore, the cooperation scenario has other remarkable advantages from technical, environmental and social perspectives. In comparison to untreated manure, AD of manure brings along multiple additional benefits, such as decreasing methane emissions and odor nuisance, as well as increasing the hygienic status and nutrient availability of manure.

Conclusions

While the production of bioenergy from manure via AD has been largely studied in the literature, few studies have investigated the cooperation dynamics among actors within the manure-based BGSC. Our paper fills this gap to understand under which conditions cooperation can be beneficial or detrimental to actors involved in the supply chain.

The benefits of the cooperation are strongly influenced by several technical, operational and economic variables whose impacts are quantified via scenario analysis. Such variables represent the effect of uncertainty on the supplier–buyer relationships in local manure markets, where waste technical quality, price and quantity vary over time. In particular, we apply computational experiments to reveal the role of such variables aimed at enhancing the development of a circular economy business models on a local level.

Considering that animal farming and cultivation activities are mostly performed in rural areas, our business model provides a closed-loop supply chain to reduce environmental impacts of secondary outputs of such activities in rural areas. The business model can be extended to a case where manure is used for biogas production, digestate is used for fertilization, agricultural residues are used as a blending biomass and the bioenergy produced is used instead of fossil-based energy in animal farming and cultivation activities. This would be a complete circular model in line with the EU’s regional development strategies, particularly when we consider that the sustainable development should be on local level. Implementing sustainability at on a local level involves efficient cooperation of local business actors on efficient use of local resources and the suitable conditions are promoted by regional authorities. Hence, our case can also be considered as a regional development model.

Several assumptions of our paper should be dealt with in future research. Our business model considers a simple case of a one-to-one relationship in which only two actors are involved in the BGSC. However, we should consider that there might be multiple farmers or biogas plants according to the available manure quantity in a region. For example, if there are ten farms producing different amounts of manure under same conditions, then the benefit will be proportionally divided among them, meaning that each farmer gains much less than the bioenergy producer. This also means that different levels of bargaining power and willingness-to-cooperate for each supplier and biogas plant might appear. Hence, total economic benefits calculated in circular business model scenario section might be distributed among involved actors according to potential contracts or benefit-sharing schemes. Similarly, other actors, such as intermediaries between suppliers and buyers or third-party logistics players or farmer coalitions, might be involved in such a business model, and the network then must be modeled considering multiple actors. In fact, further research should assess the managerial conditions of such supplier-buyer networks where small-, medium- and big-scale farms and plants are located randomly. Hence, simulation techniques such as agent-based modeling can be used to evaluate different cooperation strategies of the multiple actors approach.

Furthermore, we assume that in the cooperation scenario, all of the produced manure is sold to the bioenergy producer, i.e. the demand is equal to supply. So, our model can be used by biogas producers as decision support to invest in biogas production considering a one-on-one relationship. However, the supply-demand match is critical, and if there is a surplus or lack of manure, then the economic benefits might fluctuate, which can also be dealt with simulation techniques. Such a technique is also useful to address the dynamicity of the circular business model, which evolves over time. Further research will aim at extending our study to a more complex scenario in which more suppliers and buyers are involved in a network.

Figures

A supply chain process from an input-output perspective

Figure 1.

A supply chain process from an input-output perspective

Manure-based BGSC flowchart

Figure 2.

Manure-based BGSC flowchart

Physical input-output table of the manure-based BGSC. Colors highlight different matrices and vectors: Z is highlighted in red, f0 in green, x0 in blue, Rx̂0 in yellow, r0 in gray, Wx̂0 in sky blue and w0 in brown

Figure 3.

Physical input-output table of the manure-based BGSC. Colors highlight different matrices and vectors: Z is highlighted in red, f0 in green, x0 in blue, Rx̂0 in yellow, r0 in gray, Wx̂0 in sky blue and w0 in brown

Monetary input-output table of the manure-based BGSC

Figure 4.

Monetary input-output table of the manure-based BGSC

Actors involved in the manure-based BGSC

Figure 5.

Actors involved in the manure-based BGSC

Impact of manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Figure 6.

Impact of manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Impact of manure price and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Figure 7.

Impact of manure price and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Impact of manure dry content and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Figure 8.

Impact of manure dry content and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], transportation distance [2 km] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Impact of transportation distance and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], manure dry content [12%], organic matter content [85%] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Figure 9.

Impact of transportation distance and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], manure dry content [12%], organic matter content [85%] and manure discharge cost [15 €/t])

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], transportation distance [2 km] and manure dry content [12%], organic matter content [85%]

Figure 10.

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure quantity on benefits (with a fixed manure price [0 €/t], transportation distance [2 km] and manure dry content [12%], organic matter content [85%]

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure discharge price on benefits (with a fixed manure quantity [100,000 t], manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km])

Figure 11.

Impact of manure discharge cost and manure discharge price on benefits (with a fixed manure quantity [100,000 t], manure dry content [12 per cent], organic matter content [85 per cent], transportation distance [2 km])

References

Al Seadi, T., Rutz, D., Janssen, R. and Drosg, B. (2013), “Biomass resources for biogas production”, in Wellinger, A., Murphy, J.D., Baxter, D. (Eds), The Biogas Handbook: science, Production and Applications, Woodhead Publishing.

Albino, V., Fraccascia, L. and Savino, T. (2015), “Industrial symbiosis for a sustainable city: technical, economical and organizational issues”, Procedia Engineering, Vol. 118, pp. 950-957.

American Biogas Council (2014), “What is anaerobic digestion? Promoting the anaerobic digestion and biogas industry”, available at: www.americanbiogascouncil.org/biogas_what.asp (accessed August 2015).

Amon, T., Amon, B., Kryvoruchko, V., Zollitsch, W., Mayer, K. and Gruber, L. (2007), “Biogas production from maize and dairy cattle manure–influence of biomass composition on the methane yield”, Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment, Vol. 118 Nos 1/4, pp. 173-182.

Appels, L., Lauwers, J., Degrve, J., Helsen, L., Lievens, B., Willems, K., Van Impe, J. and Dewil, R. (2011), “Anaerobic digestion in global bio-energy production: potential and research challenges”, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, Vol. 15 No. 9, pp. 4295-4301.

Beardmore, P. (2011), “Localize west midlands. anaerobic digestion and pyrolysis - solving birmingham’s waste and energy problems? Sustainability forum: “The future of our streets?”, available at: www.bebirmingham.org.uk/uploads/Phil%20Beardmore%20Anaerobic%20Digestion%20&%20Pyrolysis%20Presentation%2003_10_11.pdf (accessed October 2015).

Berglund, M. and Borjesson, P. (2006), “Assessment of energy performance in the life-cycle of biogas production”, Biomass and Bioenergy, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 254-266.

Bocken, N.M., de Pauw, I., Bakker, C. and van der Grinten, B. (2016), “Product design and business model strategies for a circular economy”, Journal of Industrial and Production Engineering, Vol. 33 No. 5, pp. 303-308.

Bruckner, M., Giljum, S., Lutz, C. and Wiebe, K.S. (2012), “Materials embodied in international trade - global material extraction and consumption between 1995 and 2005”, Global Environmental Change, Vol. 22 No. 3, pp. 568-576.

De Korte, F. (2012), Exploring the Potential of Manure-based Energy Production in Salland, Doctoral dissertation, TU Delft, Delft University of Technology.

Deublein, D. and Steinhauser, A. (2008), Biogas from Waste and Renewable Resources: An Introduction, WILEY-VCH, Weinheim, pp. 361-388.

Ellen Macarthur Foundation (2013), “Towards the circular economy. opportunities for the consumer goods sector”, available at: www.ellenmacarthurfoundation.org/assets/downloads/publications/TCE_Report-2013.pdf (accessed December 2015).

El-Mashad, H.M. and Zhang, R. (2010), “Biogas production from co-digestion of dairy manure and food waste”, Bioresource Technology, Vol. 101 No. 11, pp. 4021-4028.

European Commission (2015), “Moving towards a circular economy”, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/circular-economy/index_en.htm (accessed October 2015).

Fraccascia, L., Magno, M. and Albino, V. (2016), “Business models for industrial symbiosis: a guide for firms”, Procedia Environmental Science Engineering and Management, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp. 83-93.

Giljum, S., Bruckner, M. and Martinez, A. (2015), “Material footprint assessment in a global input-output framework”, Journal of Industrial Ecology, Vol. 19 No. 5, pp. 792-804.

Guo, J., Dong, R., Clemens, J. and Wang, W. (2013), “Thermal modelling of the completely stirred anaerobic reactor treating pig manure at low range of mesophilic conditions”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 127, pp. 18-22.

Hall, D.O. and House, J.I. (1994), “Trees and biomass energy: carbon storage and/or fossil fuel substitution?”, Biomass and Bioenergy, Vol. 6 Nos 1/2, pp. 11-30.

International Energy Agency (2008), From 1st to 2nd Generation Biofuels Technologies. An Overview of Current Industry and R&D Activities, International Energy Agency, Paris.

International Energy Agency (2014), Key World Energy Statistics 2014, International Energy Agency, Paris.

IPCC (2014), “Summary for policymakers, in: climate change 2014: impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability”, Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New York, NY, pp. 1-32.

Lantz, M. (2012), “The economic performance of combined heat and power from biogas produced from manure in Sweden – a comparison of different CHP technologies”, Applied Energy, Vol. 98, pp. 502-511.

Massaro, V., Digiesi, S., Mossa, G. and Ranieri, L. (2015), “The sustainability of anaerobic digestion plants: a win-win strategy for public and private bodies”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 104, pp. 445-459.

McKendry, P. (2002), “Energy production from biomass (part 2): conversion technologies”, Bioresource Technology, Vol. 83 No. 1, pp. 47-54.

Miller, J. and Moyle, J. (2014), “Manure as a natural resource: alternative management opportunities. Maryland cooperative extension research works. EB-420.”, available at: http://drum.lib.umd.edu/handle/1903/1606/recent-submissions (accessed September 2015).

Miyamoto, K. (1997), Renewable Biological Systems for Alternative Sustainable Energy Production, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome.

Navaratnasamy, M., Edeogu, I., Papworth, L. (2008), “Agriculture stewardship division, alberta agriculture and rural development. economic feasibility of anaerobic digesters”, AGRI-FACTS, Agdex, pp. 768-776.

Soytas, U., Sari, R. and Ewing, B.T. (2007), “Energy consumption, income, and carbon emissions in the United States”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 62 Nos 3/4, pp. 482-489.

Wiedmann, T., Schandl, H., Lenzen, M., Moran, D., Suh, S., West, J. and Kanemoto, K. (2015), “The material footprint of nations”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of Sciences, Vol. 112 No. 20, pp. 6271-6276.

Yazan, D.M., Clancy, J. and Lovett, J.C. (2012), “Supply chains, techno-economic assessment and market development for second generation biodiesel”, in Luque, R., Melero, J.A (Eds), Advances in Biodiesel Production. Second Generation Processes and Technologies, Woodhead Publishing, Cambridge, pp. 254-280.

Yazan, D.M., Garavelli, A.C., Messeni Petruzzelli, A. and Albino, V. (2011), “The effect of spatial variables on the economic and environmental performance of bioenergy production chains”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 131 No. 1, pp. 224-233.

Further reading

Bekkering, J., Broekhuis, T.A. and Wim van Gemert, J.T. (2010), “Operational modeling of a sustainable gas supply chain”, Engineering in Life Sciences, Vol. 10 No. 6, pp. 585-594.

Center for Climate and Energy Solutions (2013), “Options and considerations for a federal carbon tax”, available at: www.c2es.org/publications/options-considerations-federal-carbon-tax (accessed August 2015).

Fankhauser, S. (1994), “The social costs of greenhouse gas emissions: an expected value approach”, The Energy Journal, Vol. 15 No. 2, pp. 157-184.

Paulot, F. and Jacob, D.J. (2014), “Hidden cost of US agricultural exports: particulate matter from ammonia emissions”, Environmental Science & Technology, Vol. 48 No. 2, pp. 903-908.

Shackley, S., Hammond, J., Gaunt, J., Ibarrola, R. and Ahmed, S. (2011), “The feasibility and costs of pyrolysis-biochar systems in North Sea Region of Europe: a case study on UK and Europe: a case study on UK and preliminary analysis of other NSR countries”, INTERREG NSR Biochar Conference Berlin, pp. 5-6.

Corresponding author

Devrim Murat Yazan can be contacted at: d.m.yazan@utwente.nl

Related articles