Explanation of terms of Grey models for decision-making

Sifeng Liu (College of Economics and Management, Nanjing University of Aeronautics and Astronautics, Nanjing, China)
Zhigeng Fang (College of Economics and Management, Nanjing University of Aeronautics and Astronautics, Nanjing, China)
Naiming Xie (College of Economics and Management, Nanjing University of Aeronautics and Astronautics, Nanjing, China)
Yingjie Yang (Centre for Computational Intelligence, De Montfort University, Leicester, UK)

Grey Systems: Theory and Application

ISSN: 2043-9377

Article publication date: 24 September 2018

Issue publication date: 24 September 2018

608

Citation

Liu, S., Fang, Z., Xie, N. and Yang, Y. (2018), "Explanation of terms of Grey models for decision-making", Grey Systems: Theory and Application, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 382-387. https://doi.org/10.1108/GS-10-2018-081

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Emerald Publishing Limited


1. Explanation of terms of Grey models for decision-making

1.1 Grey decision making

The decision making is that the action which should be taken is determined by actual situations and intended target. The nature of the decision means “decision-make” or “countermeasure-make”. There are the broad sense and narrow sense to understand the decision. In a broad sense, the decision is a whole process of a series of activities such as identifying problems, collect data, determine the target, scheme, the evaluation and implementation, feedback and correction, etc. In a narrow sense, the decision making refers to the planning option of the decision-making process, customarily referred to as the “clapper”. Others simply understand the decision as the planning option under the uncertainty condition, namely, to make a choice. It largely depends on the personal experience, attitude and determination of decision makers, as to what risks they may take. The grey decision is made in the situation that the decision model has grey elements or the normal decision model and grey model is combined, and the key research is the scheme selection problem (Deng, 1985; Liu and Lin, 2006).

1.2 Grey target for decision

According to the preset decision goal, the satisfaction value of decision-making effects is called the grey target for decision. The grey target for decision is essentially the area of satisfaction effect under the relative optimisation sense. In many cases, it is impossible to achieve an absolute optimal situation, so people often settle for the second best and generally can accept basic satisfactory results. In the situation of single objective decisions, the grey target for decision is an interval on the axis. In the multi-objective decision-making situation, the grey target for decision is a flat area or higher dimensional hyperplane area (Deng, 1990; Liu et al., 2015).

1.3 One-dimension grey target for decision

Set d 1 ( k ) and d 2 ( k ) as the upper and lower critical values of decision effect, respectively, under the target k, namely, that wish the decision-making effect value under target k should be between d 1 ( k ) and d 2 ( k ) . And S 1 = { r | d 1 ( k ) r d 2 ( k ) } is the one-dimension grey target for decision. For example, the countries formulate the development plans and hope stable economic growth at around 8 per cent. If we regard the 8 per cent as the interval between 7.6 and 8.5 per cent, so S1=[7.6 per cent, 8.5 per cent] is a one-dimension grey target for decision. Once it appears that the economic growth rate is lower than 7.6 per cent or higher than 8.5 per cent, we can think of the economy as heating up or cooling down, so the countries need to take corresponding control measures (Deng, 1985; Liu and Lin, 2011).

1.4 Two dimensions grey target for decision

Set d 1 ( 1 ) and d 2 ( 1 ) as the situation effect critical values of target 1, d 1 ( 2 ) and d 2 ( 2 ) , respectively, as the situation effect critical value of target 2, so:

S 2 = { ( r ( 1 ) , r ( 2 ) ) | d 1 ( 1 ) r ( 1 ) d 2 ( 1 ) , d 1 ( 2 ) r ( 2 ) d 2 ( 2 ) } ,
which is the two-dimension grey target for decision. In fact, a two-dimension grey target for decision is a matrix on the plane. For example, some people think that the standard height of a young man is 178–186 cm, and the weight is 65–75 kg. So S 2 = { ( r ( 1 ) , r ( 2 ) ) | 178 r ( 1 ) 186 , 65 r ( 2 ) 75 } is the corresponding two-dimension grey target for decision (Deng, 1985; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016; Liu et al., 2017).

1.5 s-dimensions decision grey target

Set d 1 ( 1 ) , d 2 ( 1 ) as d 1 ( 2 ) , d 2 ( 2 ) , , d 1 ( s ) , d 2 ( s ) , respectively, as the situation effect threshold for the target 1, 2,…,s, called the s-dimensional hyper-plane area.

S s = { ( r ( 1 ) , r ( 2 ) , , r ( s ) ) | d 1 ( 1 ) r ( 1 ) d 2 ( 1 ) , d 1 ( 2 ) r ( 2 ) d 2 ( 2 ) , , d 1 ( s ) r ( s ) d 2 ( s ) } is the s-dimensional decision grey target (Deng, 1985; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016; Liu et al., 2017).

1.6 s-dimensions spherical grey target

Set r 0 = ( r 0 ( 1 ) , r 0 ( 2 ) , , r 0 ( s ) ) as optimal effect vector, say R s = { ( r ( 1 ) , r ( 2 ) , , r ( s ) ) | ( r ( 1 ) r 0 ( 1 ) ) 2 + ( r ( 2 ) r 0 ( 2 ) ) 2 + + ( r ( s ) r 0 ( s ) ) 2 R 2 } is the s-dimensions spherical grey target which use r 0 = ( r 0 ( 1 ) , r 0 ( 2 ) , , r 0 ( s ) ) as the bull’s-eye and R as radius (Deng, 1985; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016, Liu et al., 2017).

1.7 Bull’s-eye distance

Set r 1 = ( r 1 ( 1 ) , r 1 ( 2 ) , , r 1 ( s ) ) R , and say | r 1 r 0 | = [ ( r 1 ( 1 ) r 0 ( 1 ) ) 2 + ( r 1 ( 2 ) r 0 ( 2 ) ) 2 + + ( r 1 ( s ) r 0 ( s ) ) 2 ] 1 / 2 is the bull’s-eye distance of vector r1. Bull’s-eye distance value reflects the merits of the decision-making vector.

Unlike the rectangular grey target, the spherical decision-making grey target can determine the merits of the decision-making vector by the comparison of the bull’s-eye distance number (Deng, 1985; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016, Liu et al., 2017).

1.8 The effect measure of benefit-type objective

Set k a efficiency target, that is the bigger the sample values of decision targeted effects, the better; set grey target for decision under target k as u i j ( k ) [ u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , max i max j { u i j ( k ) } ] , so u i 0 j 0 ( k ) is the target threshold effect of k, then:

r i j ( k ) = u i j ( k ) u i 0 j 0 ( k ) max i max j { u i j ( k ) } u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ,
which is called the effect measure of benefit-type objective. The effect measure of benefit-type objective reflects the proximity of the effect sample values and maximum effect sample values and the extent away from the target threshold effect (Liu et al., 2013, 2017, Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.9 The effect measure of cost-type objective

Set k a the cost-type target, that is the smaller the sample values of decision targeted effects, the better; set grey target for decision under target k as u i j ( k ) [ min i min j { u i j ( k ) } , u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ] , so u i 0 j 0 ( k ) is the target threshold effect of k, then:

r i j ( k ) = u i 0 j 0 ( k ) u i j ( k ) u i 0 j 0 ( k ) min i min j { u i j ( k ) } ,
which is called the effect measure of cost-type objectives. The effect measure of cost-type objectives reflects the proximity of the effect sample values and minimum effect sample values and the extent away from the target threshold effect. (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.10 The lower effect measure of moderate value type objective

Set k a moderate type target, that is the closer the sample values towards a moderate value A, the better; set grey target for decision under target k as u i j ( k ) [ A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ] , so A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , respectively, are the lower effect threshold and the upper effect threshold under target k, when u i j ( k ) [ A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , A ] , say:

r i j ( k ) = u i j ( k ) A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ,
which is the lower effect measure of moderate value type objective.

The lower effect measure of moderate value type objective reflect the proximity of the effect sample values that are less than the moderate value A and the moderate value and the extent away from the lower threshold effect (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.11 The upper effect measure of moderate value type objective

Set k a moderate type target, that is the closer the sample values towards a moderate value A, the better; set the grey target for decision under target k as u i j ( k ) [ A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ] , so A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) and A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , respectively, are the lower effect threshold and the upper effect threshold under target k, when u i j ( k ) [ A , A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ] , say:

r i j ( k ) = A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) u i j ( k ) u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ,

which is the upper effect measure of moderate value type objective.

The upper effect measure of the moderate value type objective reflects the proximity of the effect sample values more than the moderate value A and the moderate value and the extent away from the upper threshold effect (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.12 Out of target

There are the following four kinds of situations:

  1. the effect value of benefit-type objective less than the threshold u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , that is u i j ( k ) < u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ;

  2. the effect value of cost-type objective more than the threshold u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , that is u i j ( k ) > u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ;

  3. the effect value of moderate type objective less than the lower effect threshold A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , that is u i j ( k ) < A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ; and

  4. the effect value of moderate type objective more than the upper effect threshold A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , that is u i j ( k ) > A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) .

These are called off-target (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.13 Normality assumptions of effect measures

It is done in order to make all kinds of effect measures of objectives to meet regulatory, which is:

r i j ( k ) [ 1 , 1 ] .

For a benefit-type objective, might as well set u i j ( k ) max i max j { u i j ( k ) } + 2 u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ; for a cost-type objective, might as well set u i j ( k ) min i min j { u i j ( k ) } + 2 u i 0 j 0 ( k ) ; and for situations in which the effect value of moderate type objective is less than the lower effect threshold A u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , might as well set u i j ( k ) A 2 u i 0 j 0 ( k ) .

For the situation in which the effect value of moderate type objective is more than the upper effect threshold A + u i 0 j 0 ( k ) , might as well set u i j ( k ) A + 2 u i 0 j 0 ( k ) (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.14 Uniform effect measure

Uniform effect measures the effect measure of decision objective to meet the following conditions:

r i j ( k ) ( i = 1 , 2 , , n ; j = 1 , 2 , , m ; k = 1 , 2 , , s ) ,

where there are the following uniform effect measures: r i j ( k ) is non-dimensional; the effect is more ideal, r i j ( k ) is larger; and r i j ( k ) [ 1 , 1 ] . In the case of k target, r i j ( k ) [ 0 , 1 ] ; In the case of k off-target, r i j ( k ) [ 1 , 0 ] .

Accordingly, it is not difficult to give the definition consistent effect measure vectors and a uniform effect measure matrix (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.15 Synthetic effect measure

Set ηk(k=1, 2,…,s) as the decision-making power of the target k, and k = 1 s η k = 1 and r i j ( k ) ( i = 1 , 2 , , n ; j = 1 , 2 , , m ; k = 1 , 2 , , s ) are the uniform effect measures, then say k = 1 s η k r i j ( k ) is the synthetic effect measure of the decision target, still referred to as r i j = k = 1 s η k r i j ( k ) .

Synthetic effect measure r i j ( k ) [ 0 , 1 ] belongs to the target situation. Synthetic effect measure r i j ( k ) [ 1 , 0 ] belongs to missed situations. In the case of target, we can also compare the level of the synthetic effect measure rij(i=1, 2,…,n; j=1, 2,…,m) to judge pros and cons of the cases ai (i=1, 2,…,n), counter-measures bj (j=1, 2,…,m) and decision sij=(ai, bj) (i=1, 2,…,n, j=1, 2,…,m) (Liu et al., 2013, 2017; Liu, Yingjie, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Yingjie, Naiming, Jeffrey, 2016; Liu, Tao, Xie et al., 2016).

1.16 Normalised clustering coefficient vector

Assuming that σ i = ( σ i 1 , σ i 2 , , σ i s ) , i = 1 , 2 , , n are n clustering coefficient vectors, let δ i k = σ i k / k = 1 s σ i k , δ i k is called the normalised clustering coefficient vector of decision-making object i belonging to class k (Liu et al., 2014, 2017, 2018).

1.17 The maximum component of clustering coefficient vector

Assume that max 1 k s { δ i k } = δ i k * , then δ i k * is called the maximum component of clustering coefficient vector δi (Liu et al., 2014, 2017, 2018).

1.18 The weight vector group of kernel clustering

Assume that there are s classes of decision-making, and real numbers wk ⩾ 0, k=1, 2,…,s, then let:

η 1 = 1 k = 1 s w k ( w s , w s 1 , w s 2 , , w 1 ) ,
η 2 = 1 w s 1 + k = 2 s w k ( w s 1 , w s , w s 1 , w s 2 , , w 2 ) ,
η 3 = 1 w s 1 + w s 2 + k = 3 s w k ( w s 2 , w s 1 , w s , w s 1 , , w 3 ) ,
η k = 1 i = s k + 1 s 1 w i + i = k s w i ( w s k + 1 , w s k + 2 , , w s 1 , w s , w s 1 , , w k ) ,
η s 1 = 1 w s 1 + k = 2 s w k ( w 2 , w 3 , , w s 1 , w s , w s 1 ) ,
η s = 1 k = 1 s w k ( w 1 , w 2 , w 3 , , w s 1 , w s ) ,

where ηk(k=1, 2,…,s) is called a weight vector group of kernel clustering about class k.

The s-dimensional vector η k = ( η k 1 , η k 2 , , η k s ) ( k = 1 , 2 , , s ) is the multiplication of scalar a k = 1 / ( i = s k + 1 s 1 w i + i = k s w i ) with vector ζk, where the function of the scalar factor ak is to ensure ηk(k=1, 2,…,s) is a unit vector. Also, the kth component of vector factor ζk(k=1, 2,…,s) is ws, which is the maximum component of ζk. Then the kth component ws can be taken as a centre, and the other components on both sides of the kth component ws descend step by step. The kth component where the largest contribution for the decision-making object belongs to grey class k, so the kth component of ζk should take the maximum weight ws. The values of other components are set by the principle which states that “the component which is closest to the kth component has the largest contribution for object I belonging to class k, so it is given the largest weight; the component which is farthest from the kth component has the smallest contribution for object I belonging to class k, so it is given the smallest weight” (Liu et al., 2014, 2017, 2018).

1.19 The weighted coefficient vector of kernel clustering for decision making

Assume there are n decision objects and s different grey classes, then ω i k = η k δ i T is called the weighted coefficient of kernel clustering for the decision making of object i about grey class k. And:

ω i = ( ω i 1 , ω i 2 , , ω i s ) ; i = 1 , 2 , , n ,
which is called the weighted coefficient vector of kernel clustering for the decision making of object i (Liu et al., 2014, 2017, 2018).

References

Deng, J.L. (1985), Grey Control Systems, Press of Huazhong University of Science and Technology, Wuhan (in Chinese).

Deng, J.L. (1990), A Course in Grey Systems Theory, Press of Huazhong University of Science and Technology, Wuhan (in Chinese).

Liu, S., Hongyang, Z. and Yingjie, Y. (2018), “On paradox of rule of maximum value and its solution”, Systems Engineering: Theory and Practice, Vol. 38 No. 6, pp. 109-115.

Liu, S., Jeffrey, F. and Yingjie, Y. (2015), “Grey system: thinking, methods, and models with applications”, Contemporary Issues in Systems Science and Engineering, John Wiley & Sons, pp. 153-224.

Liu, S., Yingjie, Y. and Jeffrey, F. (2016), Grey Data Analysis: Methods, Models and Applications, Springer-Verlag.

Liu, S., Zhigeng, F. and Yingjie, Y. (2014), “On the two stages decision model with grey synthetic measure and a betterment of triangular whitenization weight function”, Control and Decision, Vol. 29 No. 7, pp. 1232-1238.

Liu, S., Yingjie, Y., Naiming, X. and Jeffrey, F. (2016), “New progress of grey system theory in the new millennium”, Grey Systems Theory and Application, Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 2-31.

Liu, S., Xu, B., Jeffrey, F., Chen, Y. and Yingjie, Y. (2013), “On uniform effect measure functions and a weighted multi-attribute grey target decision model”, The Journal of Grey System, Vol. 25 No. 1, pp. 1-11.

Liu, S., Tao, L., Xie, N. et al. (2016), “On the new model system and framework of grey system theory”, The Journal of Grey System, Vol. 28 No. 1, pp. 1-15.

Liu, S.F. and Lin, Y. (2006), Grey Information: Theory and Practical Applications, Springer-Verlag, London.

Liu, S.F. and Lin, Y. (2011), Grey Systems Theory and Applications, Springer-Verlag, Berlin and Heidelberg.

Liu, S.F. et al. (2017), Grey System Theory and Its Application, 8th ed., Science Press, Beijing (in Chinese).

Related articles