Quantum game perspective on green product optimal pricing under emission reduction cooperation of dual-channel supply chain

Yu-Chung Chang (School of Management, Xiamen University Tan Kah Kee College, Zhangzhou, China)

Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing

ISSN: 0885-8624

Article publication date: 3 March 2023

Issue publication date: 18 December 2023

1085

Abstract

Purpose

From the quantum game perspective, this paper aims to study a green product optimal pricing problem of the dual-channel supply chain under the cooperation of the retailer and manufacturer to reduce carbon emissions.

Design/methodology/approach

The decentralized and centralized decision-making optimal prices and profits are obtained by establishing the classical and quantum game models. Then the classical game and quantum game are compared.

Findings

When the quantum entanglement is greater than 0, the selling prices of the quantum model are higher than the classical model. Through theoretical research and numerical analysis results, centralized decision-making is more economical and efficient than decentralized decision-making. Publicity and education on carbon emission reduction for consumers will help consumers accept carbon emission reduction products with slightly higher prices. When the emission reduction increases too fast, the cost of emission reduction will form a significant burden and affect the profits of manufacturers and supply chain systems.

Originality/value

From the perspective of the quantum game, the author explores the optimal prices of green product and compares them with the classical game.

Keywords

Citation

Chang, Y.-C. (2023), "Quantum game perspective on green product optimal pricing under emission reduction cooperation of dual-channel supply chain", Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, Vol. 38 No. 13, pp. 74-91. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBIM-02-2022-0094

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, Yu-Chung Chang.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial & non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Over the past 20 years to today, one of the environmental problems about which the international community is most concerned is climate warming. To cope with global warming and find feasible solutions, government officials, scientists and environmentalists all over the world have conducted extensive discussions and cooperation. The carbon tax is proposed in these research and discussions. It is a tax on carbon dioxide emissions because carbon dioxide emissions have always been the main cause of climate warming. At present, many countries reduce carbon emissions by levying carbon taxes.

When climate change and air pollution have threatened the economies, ecosystems and sustainable lifestyles of people, we beings must make changes, improve our awareness of environmental protection, change our production and consumption habits, develop new technologies and reduce carbon emissions, so that the environmental changes brought about by human beings are within the scope of ecological resilience. Ecological resilience refers to the ability of an ecosystem to withstand external interference to maintain its original state. Ecological resilience determines the sustainable relationship within an ecosystem (Holling, 1973).

The ultimate solution to climate warming is to develop a low-carbon lifestyle. As individuals, we should avoid the waste of water, food, clothing, paper, electricity and other materials. In terms of transportation, we should try to take public transport or use new energy vehicles and bicycles should be used for short distances. Domestic water can be recycled, and energy-saving appliances and green products should be used. Garbage classification and waste materials recycling should be done well. Enterprises should use more environment-friendly and recyclable materials for product production, building and construction and should develop new technologies to reduce carbon emissions and other industrial wastes. The low-carbon lifestyle requires people to change their living and consumption habits and enterprises to invest in carbon emission reduction costs. Therefore, the government should establish some transmission mechanisms to promote people's green living awareness and green habits and formulate laws and incentive measures to encourage enterprises to green production. Government initiatives, government arrangements and economic incentives support are very important to develop a low-carbon lifestyle (Sampford, 2009). The carbon tax policy is a potentially significant tool to encourage the development of low-carbon life and prevent greenhouse gas emissions that lead to climate change.

Among emerging market countries, one of China's important strategies to deal with climate change is to select some important production cities as low-carbon pilot cities (LCPCs), accumulate low-carbon development experience through government initiatives and economic incentive support and better achieve the committed carbon emission reduction goals (Qiu et al., 2021). The LCPCs strategy aims to establish a sustainable energy ecosystem, so as to reduce carbon emissions in the production and consumption process and promote green life awareness and green habits through the transmission mechanisms, which can play a role in inducing residents' low-carbon choices. The study found that LCPCs can promote the green transformation of the residents' lifestyle, reducing the carbon emissions of life by about 15.3% (Liu and Xu, 2022). The Brazilian Government is committed to developing bioenergy-livestock integrated (BLI) systems, which can not only meet future agricultural needs but also relieve land use pressure and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. According to the study, BLI systems have low greenhouse gas emissions and the mitigation rates of meat and ethanol production are 32% and 22%, respectively. However, BLI systems have many potential obstacles, including operational complexity, specific technical know-how and the need for economic incentives (Nariê et al., 2021). Therefore, government initiatives and economic incentives support are very important in the development of the BLI systems in Brazil.

Even if the government takes action and adopts economic incentive support to reduce the negative impact of the carbon tax on the macroeconomy, enterprises themselves will still face the increase of carbon tax and carbon emission reduction production costs. These carbon emission reduction costs may lead to capital shortage and form the problem of financial constraints for enterprises. Enterprises' initiatives of green manufacturing may be reduced by financial constraints (Cao et al., 2020). Therefore, seeking partners to invest in emission reduction costs to avoid capital shortage has become a solution to the problem of financial constraints. This also makes it possible for the manufacturer and the government, or the manufacturer and partners, to form a game situation, respectively.

In terms of business operation, managers must consider the cost of the carbon tax and the social responsibility of green production and then invest in carbon emission reduction. However, to avoid the financial risk caused by the high cost of carbon emission reduction, a successful manager should explore and understand how to find investment partners for carbon emission reduction and how to conduct investment cooperation on carbon emission reduction. Therefore, this paper wants to discuss how business managers should make decisions when facing carbon emission reduction investment cooperation by establishing a game model.

Supply chain management is the focal research topic in industrial marketing management. Many studies focused on buyer–supplier relationships and other procurement and supply management topics (Ellram and Murfield, 2019). Golgeci and Gligor (2017) studied the relationship between key marketing and supply chain management capabilities, as well as the integration mechanism to form the basic mechanism of capacity relationship. They found that the relationship between strategic marketing and supply chain management capabilities follows a specific pattern. Applying organizational dynamics to key marketing and supply chain management can better understand the relationship between these capabilities. Therefore, the study of the supply chain will help us to formulate industrial marketing strategies.

With e-commerce booming, the dual-channel supply chain is becoming popular. It is a supply chain in which retail channels and online channels coexist. The manufacturer and retailer in the dual-channel supply chain are in the relationship of coexistence of competition and cooperation, so the competitive and cooperative relationship between the two sides forms a game situation.

Is it better for manufacturers and retailers in the dual-channel supply chain to do investment cooperation in carbon emission reduction? Or is it better not to do investment cooperation? It is a problem worthy of discussion. When the two sides conduct carbon emission reduction investment cooperation, how to set the online sales price and the retailer's sales price so as to maximize the benefits of the dual-channel supply chain system is the focus of the managers of both sides. For business managers, these problems are decision-making problems for choosing the optimal business strategies, and they should be deeply understood and explored by every manager. From the perspective of game theory, when both sides of the dual-channel supply chain begin to compete in price or cooperate in investment, the relationships of competition and cooperation between the two sides form a quantum entanglement phenomenon. The faster the reaction of competition and cooperation is, the higher the quantum entanglement degree is. Therefore, such a problem is very suitable for starting from the perspective of the quantum game.

In this paper, we shall explore the emission reduction cooperation decision of the dual-channel supply chain from the perspective of the quantum game. Section 2 presents a literature review, including the theoretical background of game theory, theories and applications of quantum games, and the green product and emission reduction in channel cooperation. Section 3 presents the basic assumptions of the research model. Section 4, we construct the carbon tax-constrained emission reduction investment cooperation model in the dual-channel supply chain from the perspective of the quantum game, and the optimal decision strategy is deduced. In addition, it also includes the management significance of our theoretical model. Section 5 presents the numerical simulation results of the models. Section 6 offers the conclusion and suggestion, which not only compares the quantum game model with the classical game model but also concludes this paper. Then, the research results and relevant recommendations on business and management are summarized.

2. Literature review

2.1 Theoretical background of game theory

In this subsection, we will introduce the game theory methods used in this paper. Relevant theoretical knowledge can refer to Nash (1950), Vives (1990), Fudenberg and Tirole (1991) and et al. (2016).

2.1.1 Basic concepts of game theory

Game theory is a decision-making method, which originates from economic problems in society and is the process and method for game players to formulate their optimal strategies in the interaction and mutual influence. The basic elements of the game mainly include players, information, action, utility function (payoff), order and equilibrium.

The player is the main body that can make the game strategy and can maximize his payoff by making rational decisions. Information refers to the knowledge that game players can recognize and master in the game process. Before making decisions, each player will analyze the information that he has and then make decisions that are most beneficial to him, so as to optimize their game returns. Action refers to the collection of all strategies that can be made by the players under the existing game conditions. After each game player rationally formulates his strategies, he will get an expected benefit, which is the payoff of this game player and it is the optimization goal of each game player. In the process of the game, the strategies formulated by the players have an order. Each player has his own optimal game strategy, and equilibrium refers to the combination of optimal game strategies of each player.

It is assumed that the process of each player making strategies is rational, and each player can obtain all the game information. Use G = {N, 핊, (Ui)i∈N} to represent a game with N players, where 핊 = S1 × … × SN is the strategy space defined as the Cartesian products of all individual strategy sets Si, and the payoff Ui of player i is a function of the strategy. In the game G, for any strategy SiSi, there is a strategy SiSi so that Ui(Si*,Si)Ui(Si,Si) holds, where Si refers to the joint strategy adopted by the opponents of player i, we say that Si* is the optimal response strategy of player i. The domain of Si is denoted by Si.

Definition 1. The (pure) strategy profile (S1*,,SN*)S is a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if Ui(Si*,Si*)Ui(Si,Si*) for all SiSi and iN.

Definition 2. Given Si, a mixed strategy ρi is a probability distribution over Si. The symbol Δ¯ represents the Cartesian products Δ1 × … × ΔN where each Δi refers to the set of all probability distributions over Si, with ρi ∈ Δi.

Definition 3. The mixed strategy profile (ρ1*,,ρN*) is a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if Ui(ρi*,ρi*)Ui(ρi,ρi*) for all ρiΔi and iN.

Nash equilibrium is the most important concept in game theory. When the players of a game are at a Nash equilibrium, there is no one player can obtain the gain by deviating from this Nash equilibrium point. The relevant theorems of Nash equilibrium are as follows. For proof, see Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), pp. 29–30, 34–35 and 35–36.

Nash equilibrium existence theorem (Nash, 1950). Every finite strategy game has a Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies.

Pure-strategy Nash equilibrium existence theorem (Debreu, 1952; Fan, 1952; Glicksberg, 1952). A game has a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium if, for all iN, the strategy set Si is a nonempty, convex and compact subset of the Euclidean space and the utility function Ui is continuous and quasi-concave in each Si.

Mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium existence theorem (Glicksberg, 1952). A game has a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium if, for all iN, the strategy set Si is a nonempty compact subset of a metric space and the utility function Ui is continuous.

2.1.2 Problem of unconstrained maximization

The problem of unconstrained maximization is that of choosing values of n variables such that the objective function has a maximum.

Theorem on first-order derivative conditions (Arrow and Michael, 1981). Let F(x) be a real-valued differentiable function on X, where X is a given subset of Euclidean space En. If F(x*) is a local maximum x* ∈ X, then:

(1)Fx(x*)=(Fx1(x*),,Fxn(x*))=0.

Theorem on second-order derivative conditions (Arrow and Michael, 1981). Let F(x) be a twice differentiable real-valued function with continuous second-order partial derivatives. If F(x*) is a local maximum x* ∈ X, then the n × n Hessian matrix of second-order partial derivatives of F(x):

(2)2Fx2(x)=[(2Fxixj(x))ij]n×n
is negative semidefinite at x*, that is, ht2Fx2(x)h0 for all n × 1 column vectors h.

2.1.3 Noncooperative game analysis

In the noncooperative game model, each player makes decisions to aim for his optimal payoff. When making strategies, each player in the game only cares about whether his own payoff can reach the optimal level but not whether the payoffs of other players are affected (Vives, 1990).

If there are only two manufacturers T1 and T2 producing the same product in the market, the demand Di is a function of the sell price Pi, and Di decreases with the increase of sell price Pi, for each i = 1, 2. The profit function of the manufacturer Ti is πi = Pi × Di(Pi), i = 1, 2. The profit function of the system is πs = π1 + π2.

In the noncooperative game model, Ti decides the selling price Pi to aim for the optimal profit πi. If πi has a maximum at Pi*, from the first derivative condition we have πiPi(Pi*)=0, for each i = 0, 1. From the second derivative condition, we have 2π12P1(P1*)0 and 2π22P2( P2*)0.

2.1.4 Cooperative game analysis

The cooperative game, also known as a positive-sum game, means that the interests of both sides of the game have increased, or at least the interests of one side have increased, whereas the interests of the other side are not damaged, so the interests of the whole system have increased. In the cooperative game model, each player aims to maximize the gain of the system (Ichiishi and Idzik, 1990).

In the cooperative game model, T1 and T2 decide the selling price P1 and P2 together, with the goal of maximizing the system profit πs. If πs has a maximum at (P1c,P2c), from the first derivative condition we have πsPi(P1c,P2c)=0, for all i = 0, 1. From the second derivative condition, we have the 2 × 2 Hessian matrix:

[2πs2P1(P1c,P2c)2πsP2P1(P1c,P2c)2πsP1P2(P1c,P2c)2πs2P2(P1c,P2c)]
is negative semidefinite, that is, ht2πsP2P1(P1c,P2c)h0 for all 2 × 1 column vectors h. Choose h = (1,0) and h = (0,1), we have 2πs2Pi(P1c,P2c)0 for all i = 1, 2.

2.2 Quantum game theory

In 1999, Meyer explored the classical game theory from the perspective of a quantum algorithm and found that an optimal quantum player always beats an opponent which uses an optimal mixed strategy (Meyer, 1999). Eisert et al. (1999) introduced quantum strategy into the prisoner's dilemma and found that the game will no longer constitute a dilemma if the quantum strategy is allowed. There is a lot of research evidence that quantum game solves some of the difficult problems encountered in classical game theory and that quantum game is more flexible than classical game (Flitney and Hollenberg, 2007; Hong et al., 2008).

2.2.1 Quantum game with n players

A quantum game with n players has the structure shown in Figure 1. This game starts from quantum state |vac1⊗|vac2⊗ … |vac〉n. The quantum entangled state:

(3)|ψ=J^(γ)(|vac1|vac2|vacn)
can be transformed from the initial state through a unitary operator:
(4)J^(γ)=exp{γ[i,j=1, ijn(a^j+a^i+a^ja^i)]},
where γ is called the quantum entanglement degree and a^j+ and a^j are the creation operator and annihilation operator, respectively. For the player j, the final observation is X^j=(a^j++a^j)/2, which is the position operator. Let i=1 and P^j=i(a^j+a^j)/2 , P^j represents the momentum operator of j. If X^j can be accurately measured, let x^j be the measurement result. When the decision is production quantity qj, we can get qj=x^j. When the decision is selling price pj, we can get pj=x^j.

The action strategies of player j are determined by the unitary operator D^j. The set of strategies of the player j is:

(5)Sj={D^j(xj)=exp(ixjP^j) | xj(0,+)},j=1, 2,n.

The unitary operator J^+ can measure the state, the final state is expressed as:

(6)|ψf=J^(γ)+(D^1D^2D^n)J^(γ)(|vac1|vac2|vacn).

For j = 1, 2, … n, it can be proved by mathematical induction that J^(γ)+D^j(xj)J^(γ) is as follows (Zhou et al., 2005):

(7)exp{ixj[P^j1n(e(n1)γ+(n1)eγ)+i=1, ijnP^i1n(e(n1)γeγ)]}.

2.2.2 Quantum game with two players

Consider a quantum game with two players T1 and T2, they decide the selling price p1 and p2 to achieve their optimal profit πi. The set of strategies of the player j is:

(8)Sj={D^j(xj)=exp(ixjP^j) | xj(0,+)},j=1,2.

The final state is:

(9)|ψf=J^(γ)+(D^1D^2)J^(γ)(|vac1|vac2).

From equation (7), we have:

(10)J^(γ)+D^1(x1)J^(γ)=exp{ix1[P^112(eγ+eγ)+P^212(eγeγ)]},
(11)J^(γ)+D^2(x2)J^(γ)=exp{ix2[P^212(eγ+eγ)+P^112(eγeγ)]}.

Because sinh γ = (eγeγ)/2 and cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2, we can obtain:

(12)J^(γ)+D^1(x1)J^(γ)=exp{ix1[P^1coshγ+P^2sinhγ]},
(13)J^(γ)+D^2(x2)J^(γ)=exp{ix2[P^2coshγ+P^1sinhγ]}.

Therefore:

(14)|ψf=J^(γ)+[D^1(x1)D^2(x2)]J^(γ)=exp{− ix1[P^1coshγ+P^2sinhγ]}× exp{− ix2[P^2coshγ+P^1sinhγ]}.

The final state becomes (Li et al., 2002):

(15)|ψf=exp{i(x1 coshγ+x2 sinhγ)P^1}|vac1exp{i(x2 coshγ+x1 sinhγ)P^2}|vac2.

When the decision is the selling price p1 and p2, we can get:

(16)p1=x^1=x1 coshγ+x2 sinhγ,
(17)p2=x^2=x2 coshγ+x1 sinhγ.

Then, the relationships between the quantum strategies and the prices are:

(18)p1(x1,x2)=x1 coshγ+x2 sinhγ,
(19)p2(x1,x2)=x2 coshγ+x1 sinhγ.

2.3 Research on the application of game theory

2.3.1 Application of game theory in supply chain

Many researchers explore the pricing problem and management strategies in the supply chain by using the game theory (Chiang et al., 2003). Yao and Liu (2005) used Bertrand and Stackelberg model to solve the dual-channel price competition problem and obtained the optimal decision. Yan and Zhi (2009) found that online channels are not always harmful to retailers. Retailers can rise higher sales by negotiating with manufacturers to reduce wholesale prices and provide better retail services.

Hua et al. (2010) studied the impact of the delivery lead time of the direct channel on the channel members' pricing, they derived the optimal delivery lead time and optimal price in the dual-channel supply chain by using the two-stage optimization technique and Stackelberg game. Modak and Kelle (2019) further studied the optimal ordering and pricing strategy of a dual-channel supply chain with price and delivery time dependent on stochastic customer demand. They examined the impact of delivery lead time and customer channel preference on the optimal operation. And then use the hybrid all-unit quantity discount in the franchise fee contract to coordinate the supply chain.

Sharma and Jain (2020) established a retailer fairness model to discuss the impact of retailer's fairness concerns on partners' pricing strategies and profits. The optimal pricing strategy of channel members is derived by using the established model.

2.3.2 Application of game theory in carbon reduction

Feng et al. (2017) established a government and manufacturer conflict of interest game model to discuss the responses of a manufacturer to government low-carbon regulations. They found the strategies that a manufacturer and government should adopt to maximize profits under the reducing carbon emissions situation. Zhi et al. (2019) established a collaborative carbon emission reduction (CCER) evolutionary game model to study the role of Chinese Government policies in promoting cooperative emission reduction between suppliers and manufacturers. They found that the CCER evolution process is affected by the initial state of the supply chain, cost, additional income and investment risks related to CCER.

Adetutu et al. (2020) found that energy efficiency is the least response of enterprises to the UK climate change levy (CCL), whereas factor substitution and technological progress are the main response of enterprises to CCL. Liu et al. (2020) established a model of auto parts low-carbon supply chain to explore the optimal decision strategy. In the agricultural supply chain, if the retailers participate in the investment plan to help manufacturers to purchase equipment or develop technologies to reduce carbon emissions, the overall supply chain profit can be improved. Therefore, the environment-protecting goal and the profit-increasing goal can both be achieved, when manufacturers and retailers form a centralized supply chain (Liu et al., 2021).

2.4 Impact of the carbon tax

In practical policy practice, carbon tax collection and related environmental policies may result in the spatial transfer of pollution. Fredriksson and Millimet (2002) found that there is strategic interaction in environmental regulation between regions. The asymmetry of regional environmental regulation policies will prompt enterprises to make site selection decisions, that is, to move from areas with strong environmental regulation to areas with weak environmental regulation, so as to reduce the production costs of enterprises. Enterprises may also move from areas with poor ecological resilience to areas with high ecological resilience. If the spatial transfer of pollution and ecological resilience do not be considered, only focus on the impact of the carbon tax on the economy; although the imposition of a carbon tax may have a negative impact on the economy, there is a lot of research evidence that the imposition of a carbon tax can indeed reduce greenhouse gas emissions and improve the impact of climate warming.

Lee et al. (2008) compared the Influence on the economy among different industrial sectors by carbon emission policies. They found that carbon tax is the only policy that has an adverse influence. The international competitive advantage of energy-intensive industries is affected by the carbon tax (Zhao, 2011). Through the comparison of the carbon tax schemes' macroeconomic effects and their influences, Liang et al. (2007) believe that although levy carbon tax has a negative influence, it can be alleviated by properly relieving or subsidizing. Marron and Toder (2014) point out that designing a reasonable carbon tax collection method can decrease the risk caused by climate change, minimize the emission reduction cost, incite the innovation of low-carbon technology and increase new public revenue. Murray and Rivers (2015) summed the experience and results in British Columbia. They found that greenhouse gas emissions have been reduced by 5%–15% under the levy of the carbon tax and only little influence on the economic activity of the whole. Over time, public support degree for carbon tax collection policy has gradually risen.

2.5 Green product and emission reduction cooperation

Since the first industrial revolution, with the development of technology and machines' mass production, massive waste pollution and carbon emission cause environmental degradation, global warming, sea level rise and ecological damage. The people of insight send out warnings and start planning for the earth's environmental protection strategies. New energy development, carbon emission reduction and green production have attracted the attention of all countries in the world (Chakravarty et al., 2009; Wang and Feng, 2021). Governments of all countries gradually adjust their industrial structures and increase subsidies and assistance for green manufacturing.

With the implementation of the low carbon policy, how to change the marketing strategy is a realistic and serious problem faced by enterprises. Lei et al. (2018) studied the manufacturer's channel selection and emission reduction decisions under carbon emission constraints. They found that the key factors affecting the channel choice of manufacturers are the product attributes and the channel preferences of consumers. It is more effective and achievable to encourage the manufacturer to develop a dual-channel mode when the government set larger carbon quotas. With more and more consumers preferring online shopping, the government can formulate more stringent emission control.

Tan et al. (2021) studied developments and trends in research on green energy and environmental technologies. They found that publications on green energy and environmental technologies have grown exponentially, China, the USA and Italy are the most active countries. Through the bibliometric method of the research frontier identification, the categories of energy, wastewater, and performance remain stable, while the discusses trending up of catalyst and carbon dioxide emissions. The areas of technical indicators in green energy and environment technologies have gradually become research hotspots. Therefore, the importance of new energy, green production, and carbon emission reduction is increasing. With the development of e-commerce and the increase in online shopping, the dual-channel supply chain model is more able to achieve the goal of “emission reduction.”

3. Basic assumptions

Figure 2 shows the research model structure, the cost of a single product produced by the manufacturer M is c, the wholesale price of this product purchased by the retailer T from the manufacturer is ω and the sales price is p0. Manufacturer M sells this product at the price of p1 through the online channel I. Assume that 0 < c < w < p0 and 0 < c < p1.

Assuming that θ is the amount of annual emission reduction and emission reduction cost is f(θ). The retailer T invests the proportion m of emission reduction cost, that is, the amount of the retailers' investment is mf(θ). The manufacturer M takes the proportion n of the profit from the total revenue R deducting the carbon tax payable Tc as the reward. The subsidy is based on the investment proportion of the retailer. Hence, the amount of subsidy is (RTc)mn.

3.1 Demand function and symbol description

Referring to the research of Banker et al. (1998), Huang and Swaminathan (2009), Mukhopadhyay et al. (2011) and Liu et al. (2021), based on prices of each channel and the consumers' sensitivity to the manufacturers' carbon emission reduction, the retailer and manufacturer’s demand are Q0 and Q1:

(20)Q0=a0b0p0+αp1+βθ,
(21)Q1=a1b1p1+αp0+βθ,
where aj is the potential market size, j = 0, 1, θ is the total annual carbon emission reduction, β is the consumers' sensitivity to the manufacturers' carbon emission reduction, 0 < α < 1 is the channel cross-elasticity coefficient between the channel of dual-channel supply chain and b0 > 1 and b1 > 1 are the direct price elasticity coefficients of the retail and online channel.

3.2 Basic assumptions

The following are the basic assumptions.

Assumption 1: Assume that the difficulty degree coefficient of reduction in carbon emissions is k and the cost of emission reduction is f(θ)=12kθ2. The emission reduction costs borne by the manufacturer and retailer are (1 – m)f(θ) and mf(θ), respectively.

Assumption 2: Assume that λ is the rate of the carbon tax and Ce is the total original carbon emission. Because the total annual carbon emission reduction is θ, the total carbon emission is (Ceθ). The manufacturer M must bear the cost of carbon tax Tc = λ(Ceθ).

Assumption 3: Customers are generally more sensitive to price than to carbon emission reduction, so we assume that bj > β, j = 0, 1.

3.3 Profit function

The retailer’s profit π0 and manufacturer’s profit π1 are:

(22)π0=(p0ω)Q0mf(θ)+mn[(ωc)Q0+(p1c)Q1λ(Ceθ)],
(23)π1=[(ωc)Q0+(p1c)Q1λ(Ceθ)](1mn)(1m)f(θ).

The dual-channel supply chain system profit πSC is:

(24)πSC=(p0c)Q0+(p1c)Q1λ(Ceθ)12kθ2.

3.4 Classical model solutions

3.4.1 Decentralized decision-making in the classical model

Using the first derivative condition, if the manufacturer and retailer aim to maximize their profit, then the second derivative conditions of the profit functions π0 and π1 are 2π0p02=2b0<0 and 2π1p12=2b1<0, respectively. Hence, the optimal prices of the classical model exist. From the first derivative condition πjpj=0, j = 0, 1:

(25)π0p0=2b0p0+α(1+mn)p1+a0+βθ+b0ωmnb0(ωc)mncα,
(26)π1p1=αp02b1p1+a1+βθ+(ωc)α+b1c,
we have:
(27) [2b0α(1+mn)α2b1][p0*p1*]=[(L1mnL2)L3],
where L1 = a0 + βθ + b0ω, L2 = b0 (ωc) + and L3 = a1 + βθ + (ωc)α + b1c. By using bj > 1 > n, m, α, j = 0, 1, the determinant:
|D|=|2b0α(1+mn)α2b1|=4b0b1(1+mn)α2>0.

By Cramer’s rule, the optimal prices are:

(28)p0*=1|D|[2b1(L1mnL2)+α(1+mn)L3],
(29)p1*=1|D|[α(L1mnL2)+2b0L3],
where L1 = a0 + βθ + b0ω, L2 = b0(ωc) + and L3 = a1 + βθ + (ωc)α + b1c.

3.4.2 Centralized decision-making in the classical model

If the manufacturer and retailer aim to maximize the overall supply chain’s profit, the dual-channel supply chain is regarded as a system. The second derivative conditions of the profit function πsc are 2πscp02=2b0<0 and 2πscp12=2b1<0. Hence, the optimal prices of the classical model exist. From the first derivative condition πscpj=0, j = 0, 1, we have:

(30) [2b02α2α2b1][P¯¯0*P¯1*]=[(L1L2)(L3ωα)].

The determinant:

|D¯|=|2b02α2α2b1|=4b0b14α2>0.

By Cramer’s rule, the optimal prices are:

(31)p¯0*=1|D¯|[2b1(L1L2)+2α(L3ωα)],
(32)p¯1*=1|D¯|[2α(L1L2)+2b0(L3ωα)],
where L1 = a0 + βθ + b0ω, L2 = b0 (ωc) + cα and L3 = a1 + βθ + (ωc)α + b1c.

4. Quantum game model under carbon tax constraints and investment cooperation

Assuming that the quantum structure of the model is as shown in Figure 3, the retailer T and manufacturer M start the quantum game from the initial state |vac0⊗|vac1. The quantum entangled state:

(33)|ψ=J^(γ)(|vac0|vac1)
can be transformed from the initial state through a unitary operator:
(34)J^(γ)=exp[iγ(X^0P^1+X^1P^0)],
where γ is called the quantum entanglement degree, X^j=(a^j++a^j)/2, P^j=i(a^j+a^j)/2, a^j+ and a^j are the creation operator and annihilation operator, respectively, j = 0, 1.

The action strategies of the retailer T and manufacturer M are determined by unitary operators D^0 and D^1. The set of strategies is:

(35)Sj={D^j(xj)=exp(xj(a^j+a^j)/2) | xj(0,+)},j=0, 1.

The unitary operator j^+ can measure the state, the final state is expressed as:

(36)|ψf=J^(γ)+(D^0D^1)J^(γ)(|vac0|vac1).

4.1 Quantum game model of cooperative emission reduction

The relationships between the quantum strategies and the prices are:

(37)p0(x0,x1)=x0 coshγ+x1 sinhγ,
(38)p1(x0,x1)=x1 coshγ+x0 sinhγ,
where sinh γ = (eγeγ)/2 and cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2. Bring equations (37) and (38) into equations (20) and (21), the demand functions Q0 and Q1 can be converted as follows:
(39)Q0=(a0+βθ)+(b0 coshγ+α sinhγ)x0+(b0 sinhγ+α coshγ)x1,
(40)Q1=(a1+βθ)+(b1 sinhγ+α coshγ)x0+(b1 coshγ+α sinhγ)x1.

4.2 Decentralized decision-making in the quantum model

When the partners in the dual-channel supply chain cooperate to reduce emissions, if the manufacturer and retailer aim to maximize their profit respectively for the quantum game, then the optimal prices p0d* and p1d* can be obtained as the following theorem.

Theorem 1. Under decentralized decision-making, the optimal prices p0d* and p1d* of the retailer and manufacturer are:

(41)p0d*=1|A|{cosh2γ [2b1(L1mnL2)+α(1+mn)L3]− coshγ sinhγ [α(L1+L2+2ωb1)]+sinh2γ [mn(2b1L2αL3)+ωα2]},
(42)p1d*=1|A|{cosh2γ[α(L1mnL2)+2b0L3]coshγsinhγ[2b0L2+αL3+ωα2]+sinh2γ[α(1+mn)L2],
where the determinant:
(43)|A|=4b0b1cosh2γ2α(b0+b1)coshγ sinhγ(1+nm)α2,
and L1 = a0 + βθ + b0ω, L2 = b0(ωc) + , L3 = a1 + βθ + b1c + α(ωc).

Proof of Theorem 1. Refer to Appendix 1.

Note: (1) If the quantum entanglement degree γ = 0, the determinant:

|A|=4b0b1(1+nm)α2=|D|,
and the optimal prices:
p0d*=1|D|[2b1(L1mnL2)+α(1+mn)L3]=p0*,p1d*=1|D|[α(L1mnL2)+2b0L3]=p1*.

In other words, when the quantum entanglement degree γ = 0, the quantum game model is consistent with the classical game model.

(2) When the quantum entanglement tends to infinity, the optimal prices are converged as follows:

p0d*=(2b1α)L1+α(L3L22ωb1+ωα)4b0b12α(b0+b1),p1d*=α(L1+L2+L3+ωα)4b0b12α(b0+b1).

(3) If the retailer does not invest in the carbon emission reduction project, in this case, m = 0 and n = 0, the determinant becomes:

|A|=4b0b1cosh2γ2α(b0+b1)coshγ sinhγα2,
and the optimal prices become:
p0d*=1|A|{cosh2γ[2b1L1+αL3]coshγsinhγ[α(L1+L2+2ωb1)]+sinh2γ[ωα2]},p1d*=1|A|{cosh2γ[αL1+2b0L3]coshγsinhγ[2b0L2+αL3+ωα2]+sinh2γ[αL2].

Corollary 1. Under decentralized decision-making, the consumers' sensitivity β and the total annual carbon emission reduction θ affect the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices. In fact:

(1) pjd*θ>0, j = 0, 1. Both the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are increasing functions of θ. When the total annual carbon emission reduction increases, the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices increase.

(2) pjd*β>0, j = 0, 1. Both the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are increasing functions of β. When the consumers' sensitivity β to carbon emission reduction increases, the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices increase.

Proof. By using sinh γ = (eγeγ)/2 and cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2, we have:

p0d*θ=β4|A|[2b1e2γ+(2b1+2α)e2γ+(4b1+2α+mnα)]>0,p1d*θ=β4|A|[(2b0e2γ+(2b0+2α)e2γ+4b0+2α]>0,p0d*β=θ4|A|[2b1e2γ+(2b1+2α)e2γ+(4b1+2α+mnα)]>0,p1d*β=θ4|A|[(2b0e2γ+(2b0+2α)e2γ+4b0+2α]>0.

This completes the proof.

4.3 Centralized decision-making in the quantum model

If the manufacturer and retailer aim to maximize the overall supply chain’s profit, the dual-channel supply chain is regarded as a system. In this case, there is no quantum phenomenon. Then, the optimal prices p0c and p1c can be obtained as the following theorem.

Theorem 2. Under centralized decision-making, the optimal prices p0c and p1c of the retailer and manufacturer are:

(44)p0c=2(b1V0+αV1)|A¯|=2[b1(L1L2)+α(L3αω)]|A¯|
(45)p1c=2(αV0+b0V1)|A¯|=2[α(L1L2)+b0(L3αω)]|A¯|
where the determinant:
(46)|A¯|=4(b0b1α2),
and V0 = a0 + βθ + b0c − αc = L1 − L2, V1 = a1 + βθ + b1cαc = L3αω.

Proof of Theorem 2. Refer to Appendix 2.

Note: Under centralized decision-making, the members of the dual-channel supply chain make decisions together, there is no competition between them, so the phenomenon of quantum entanglement does not exist. Hence, the optimal solutions of the quantum game model are consistent with the classical game. That is, p0c*=p¯0* and p1c=p¯1.

Corollary 2. Under centralized decision-making, the consumers' sensitivity β and the total annual carbon emission reduction θ affect the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices. In fact:

(1) pjc*θ>0, j = 0, 1. Both the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are increasing functions of θ. When the total annual carbon emission reduction increases, the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices increase.

(2) pjc*β>0, j = 0, 1. Both the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are increasing functions of β. When the consumers' sensitivity β to carbon emission reduction increases, the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices increase.

Proof. By a direct calculation, we have:

p0cθ=2β|A¯|[b1+α]>0,p1cθ=2β|A¯|[b0+α]>0,p0cβ=2θ|A¯|[b1+α]>0,p1cβ=2θ|A¯|[b0+α]>0.

This completes the proof.

Corollary 3. Under centralized decision-making, if:

(47)βθ>(2b0b1+α2)cb0+b1+2α,
the dual-channel supply chain system profit πSC is an increasing function of β. That is,  πSCβ>0, j = 0, 1.

Proof. By a direct calculation, we have:

 πSCβ=2θ|A¯|2[(b0+b1+2α)βθ(2b0b1+α2)c+3cα2(4b0b1α2)+U],
where U = 2(2b0b1 + a2) (a0(b1 + a) + a1(b0 + a)). If βθ>(2b0b1+α2)cb0+b1+2α, we can obtain  πSCβ>0.

4.4 Management significance

Whether decentralized or centralized decision-making is adopted, the following facts pjd*θ>0 and pjc*θ>0, j = 0, 1, in Corollary 1 and Corollary 2 tell us that the increase of the total amount of annual emission reduction θ is probably to increase the cost, and then the increased cost of emission reduction will eventually be passed on to consumers, resulting both manufacturer and retailer’s selling prices have increased. Therefore, for the sustainable development of the earth, carbon emission reduction is imperative, and consumers need to accept the rise in product prices caused by carbon emission reduction. How to develop low-cost carbon reduction technologies and equipment to reduce product prices and attract consumers has become a problem that manufacturers must face.

With consumers' attention to carbon emission reduction, consumers' sensitivity β increases. The facts pjd*β>0 and pjcβ>0, j = 0, 1, in Corollary 1 and Corollary 2 show that consumers' acceptance of the rise in sales prices of the manufacturer and retailer increases with consumers' attention to carbon emission reduction.

If the consumer's sensitivity β greater than a certain threshold, the supply chain system’s profit increases with the consumer's sensitivity β increases. Publicity and strengthening education on carbon emission reduction for consumers can improve the consumers' sensitivity to carbon emission reduction by improving consumers' attention, then encourage consumers to actively choose carbon emission reduction products and finally increase the dual-channel supply chain's profit.

To sum up, to cope with the carbon tax and make a contribution to environmental protection, business managers should invest in carbon emission reduction. But for the competitiveness of products, they should develop low-cost carbon reduction technologies. It is necessary to strengthen the environmental protection education of consumers, improve their sensitivity to carbon emission reduction and make consumers more likely to accept carbon emission reduction products.

5. Numerical analysis

This section studies the quantum model in the previous by numerical analysis and sensitivity analysis and is divided into decentralized and centralized decision-making to discuss. The parameters of numerical analysis are shown in Table 1. The numerical analysis is a simulation, but all the values of variables are reasonable and completely based on the theoretical model. For example, the direct price elasticity coefficient for the retail channel b0 and the direct price elasticity coefficient for the online channel b1 are all greater than 1, so b0 > 1 and b1 > 1. Because consumers in retail channels are more vulnerable to price fluctuations and switch to online channels to purchase, therefore, the direct price elasticity coefficient b0 of retail channels is greater than the direct price elasticity coefficient b1 of online channels. So, we assume that b0 = 1.6 and b1 = 1.5. The channel cross-elasticity coefficient α, carbon tax rate λ, investment ratio m and proportion of the profit as the reward n are all less than 1, so we choose α = 0.5, λ = 0.2, m = 0.3 and n = 0.05.

5.1 Decentralized decision-making analysis

We discuss the impact of the quantum entanglement degree γ, the customer's sensitivity β and the total amount of emission reduction θ on selling prices and profits, respectively.

5.1.1 Influence of quantum entanglement

When the partners in the dual-channel supply chain cooperate to reduce emission, choose the consumer's sensitivity β = 0.6 and the total amount of emission reduction θ = 1,000. Assuming that the quantum entanglement γ increases, the influence of quantum entanglement on selling prices and profits under decentralized decision-making is shown in Table 2 and Figure 4.

The retailer and manufacturer will adjust their product price strategy because of another's price strategy when making product sales price, so as to counter it to benefit market competition. This status of adjusting the competitive strategy according to the competitor's strategy forms a phenomenon of quantum entanglement. The significance of the quantum entanglement degree is to adjust the adjustment range or speed of the competitive strategy according to the competitor's strategy. The increase in quantum entanglement degree means that the reaction speed to competitors' strategy increases or the range of price change is increased.

From Table 2 and Figure 4 it can be seen that, with the increase of the quantum entanglement degree, the retailer price, online price and the profits of the manufacturer, retailer and overall supply chain show an upward trend. When the quantum entanglement degree is 0, the solution of the quantum model is consistent with the classical model. In this case, the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are the lowest and the profits of the retailer, manufacturer and overall supply chain system are the lowest. Therefore, the solution of the quantum game model is better than that of the classical game model.

5.1.2 Influence of the consumer's sensitivity to carbon emission reduction

Choose the quantum entanglement degree γ = 1 and the total amount of carbon emission reduction θ = 1,000. Choose the quantum entanglement degree γ = 1 and the total amount of carbon emission reduction θ = 1,000. With the consumer's sensitivity β increases, the influence of consumer's sensitivity β on selling prices and profits under decentralized decision-making is shown in Table 3 and Figure 4.

The retailer price, online price and the profits of the manufacturer, retailer and overall supply chain show an upward trend. Figure 5 verifies the result of Corollary 1 that both the retailer and manufacturer’s selling prices are increasing functions of β. When the customers' sensitivity β to carbon emission reduction is rise that represents that customers' degree of pay attention to and of acceptance for carbon emission reduction products is rise. Consumers willingly accept high-degree emission reduction products with a higher price for supporting human sustainable development. Therefore, the manufacturer and retailer can set higher selling prices for high-degree emission reduction products and obtain more profits.

5.1.3 Influence of the total amount of emission reduction

Choose the quantum entanglement degree γ = 1 and consumer's sensitivity β = 0.6 to carbon emission reduction carbon. The influence of the total emission reduction is shown in Table 4 and Figure 6.

With the increase in the total carbon emission reduction, the retailer price, online price and profit of the retailer show an upward trend, but the profits of manufacture and overall supply chain system show a trend of rising first and then falling. Figure 6 verifies the result of Corollary 1 that the selling price of the retailer and manufacturer is an increasing function of θ, respectively.

When the supply chain members cooperate to reduce emissions, the investment in purchasing equipment or developing technology to reduce carbon emissions is borne by the retailer and manufacturer. Therefore, it is bound to lead to an increase in product cost and product prices. The increase in the total carbon emission reduction θ represents an increase in the cost of capital invested in the purchase of equipment or the developing technology, resulting in the rise of product prices. The retailer, manufacturer and overall supply chain system can benefit from higher selling prices. However, when the total emission reduction increases to a certain threshold, the increase of the total emission reduction will cause the high capital cost of investing in the purchase of equipment or the development of technology, form a major burden, reduce the manufacturer’s profit and affect the profit of overall supply chain. The retailer bears part of the cost of emission reduction, which affects its profit, but it also receives part of the profit of the manufacturer, so its profit does not reduce.

5.2 Centralized decision-making analysis

Under centralized decision-making, the manufacturer and retailer make decisions with the goal to maximize the supply chain system's profit. In this case, the supply chain system is regarded as a whole to make decisions, there is no competition, so there is no quantum entanglement.

5.2.1 Influence of the customer's sensitivity to carbon emission reduction

We use the parameters in Table 1, and choose the total amount of carbon emission reduction θ = 1,000.

With the consumer's sensitivity β increases, the influence of consumer's sensitivity β on selling prices and the overall supply chain’s profit under centralized decision-making is shown in Table 5 and Figure 7. With the consumer's sensitivity β increases, the retailer price, online price and the overall supply chain's profit show an upward trend. Figure 7 verifies the result of Corollary 2 that the selling price of the retailer and manufacturer is an increasing function of β, respectively.

When the customers' sensitivity β to carbon emission reduction is on the rise, consumers are willing to accept high-degree emission reduction products at a higher price, then the dual-channel supply chain system can set higher selling prices for high-degree emission reduction products and obtain more profit.

5.2.2 Influence of the total emission reduction

Choose the consumer's sensitivity β = 0.6. Assuming the total emission reduction θ increases, the influence of the total emission reduction on prices and profit under centralized decision-making is shown in Table 6 and Figure 8.

With the increase of the total emission reduction θ, the retailer price, online price and the overall supply chain’s profit show an upward trend. Figure 8 verifies the result of Corollary 2 that the selling price of the retailer and manufacturer is an increasing function of θ, respectively.

When the dual-channel supply chain system carries out carbon emission reduction, the investment in purchasing equipment or developing carbon emission reduction technology is borne by the overall supply chain system. The increased cost is passed on to consumers, then resulting in the product's selling price increase. When the total amount of carbon emission reduction θ is less than a certain threshold, the dual-channel supply chain system can obtain higher profit from higher selling prices. However, when the total emission reduction θ is greater than a certain threshold, the investment of purchase equipment or developing technology to reduce carbon emission will cause a heavy financial burden and affect the overall supply chain’s profit. And when the total amount of annual emission reduction is too large, the profit of that year will be negative.

5.2.3 Customer's attention and the manufacturer's emission reduction

We use the parameters in Table 1 and assume that the consumer's sensitivity β to emission reduction and the total emission reduction θ increase, and the influence on profit of the overall supply chain system under centralized decision-making is shown in Figure 9. Figure 9 verifies Corollary 3, when βθ>(2b0b1+α2)cb0+b1+2α holds, the overall supply chain’s profit is an increasing function of customers' sensitivity β.

From Figure 9 it can be seen that, when the manufacturer carries out emission reduction, the overall supply chain system transfers the cost of carbon reduction to consumers and obtains high profit from the high selling prices. The more carbon emission reduction, the higher profit. However, if the customer's sensitivity β to carbon emission reduction is not high enough, the more difficult it is for customers to accept the high prices of carbon reduction products. As a result, the product of the manufacturer that strives to achieve carbon emission reduction will not be accepted by consumers because of the high price due to the high total emission reduction, finally resulting in a reduced profit.

5.2.4 Comparison of decentralized and centralized decision-making

The profit comparison between the two decision-making is shown in Figure 10. After comparing the profit between decentralized and centralized decision-making, we can find that the centralized decision-making's overall profit is higher than the decentralized decision-making's overall profit. This is because the manufacturer and retailer aim to maximize each profit under decentralized decision-making, but the overall supply chain’s profit cannot be maximized because of mutual competition. Under centralized decision-making, the retailer and manufacturer aim at maximizing the overall supply chain’s profit. Therefore, for the overall supply chain’s profit, centralized decision-making is more economical and efficient than decentralized decision-making.

6. Conclusions and suggestions

6.1 Conclusions

This paper studies a green product optimal strategy problem of the dual-channel supply chain under carbon tax constraints and emission reduction investment cooperation from the quantum game perspective. The classical game model and quantum game model of the dual-channel supply chain are established, and the optimal solutions of the two models are obtained under decentralized and centralized decision-making, respectively. Comparing the quantum game model with the classical game model, we find the following facts: when the quantum entanglement degree is 0, the solutions of the quantum model are consistent with the classical model and when the quantum entanglement degree is greater than 0, the solutions of the quantum game model are higher than the solutions of the classical game model, including the product sales price of the manufacturer and retailer and the profit of the manufacturer, retailer and the overall supply chain system. Therefore, the method of the quantum game model is better than that of the classical game model.

Through theoretical research and numerical analysis results, we have the following conclusions. For the overall supply chain system’s profit, the profit obtained by centralized decision-making is higher than that of decentralized. In other words, centralized decision-making is more economical and efficient than decentralized decision-making in pursuing the maximum overall supply chain profit.

Whether decentralized decision-making or centralized decision-making is adopted, when the dual-channel supply chain members cooperate to reduce emissions under carbon tax constraints, the increased cost to purchase equipment or develop technology will eventually be transferred to consumers, resulting the manufacturer and retailer's selling prices increase. If the consumer’s sensitivity to the manufacturer reducing carbon emissions is not enough, it will lead to low consumer recognition of the green products and will be difficult to accept high product prices, the profits of the overall system and every member in the dual-channel supply chain will reduce. Therefore, it is important to publicize and strengthen carbon emission reduction education for consumers, which can improve consumers' attention and sensitivity to manufacturers reducing carbon emissions, promote consumers to choose low-carbon products and increase the profits of the overall system and every member in the dual-channel supply chain.

The increase in the total emission reduction represents an increase in the cost of purchasing equipment or developing technology to reduce carbon emissions, resulting in an increase in product prices. The overall system and every member in the dual-channel supply chain can obtain higher profits from higher product prices. When the total amount of emission reduction increases too fast, the investment cooperation capital cost of purchasing equipment or developing technology to reduce carbon emission will be too high, forming a major burden. Too high product prices will lead consumers to reduce purchases, reduce the manufacturer's profit and affect the overall supply chain's profit. Although the retailer bears the part cost of emission reduction, which affects the retailer's profit, it also gets part of the manufacturer's profit, so the profit will not be reduced. How to develop low-cost carbon reduction technologies and equipment to reduce product prices and attract consumers is an important problem that the manufacturer must face.

6.2 Business suggestions

From the theoretical derivation and numerical simulation results of this paper, it can be found that when decentralized decision-making is adopted, the manufacturer and retailer in the dual-channel supply chain will consider their own interests and then there will be sales price competition. Because of mutual competition, the profits of the manufacturer and retailer as well as the profits of the dual-channel supply chain system cannot be maximized. However, under centralized decision-making, the goal of the manufacturer and retailer is to maximize the profit of the dual-channel supply chain system. And then the result is that not only the profit of the dual-channel supply chain system is maximized but also the profits of the manufacturer and retailer are higher than when they adopt decentralized decision-making. Therefore, when conducting business cooperation, managers of enterprises should try their best to get rid of selfishness and take the overall interests as the starting point to maximize the benefits of business cooperation.

Enterprises' investment in carbon emission reduction not only reflects their conscience but also fulfills their social responsibilities and should be more publicity promoted given to people. Strengthening the publicity of enterprises on carbon emission reduction investment and results can not only establish a good image of enterprises but also attract consumers' attention, improve their sensitivity to carbon emission reduction and awaken their environmental awareness. When consumers' awareness of environmental protection is awakened, they may start to pursue a low-carbon lifestyle, which will be beneficial to the sustainability of the environment and the improvement of the earth's ecosystem. Based on the theoretical derivation and numerical analysis simulation results of this paper, it can be found that the increased sensitivity of consumers to carbon emission reduction will promote consumers to choose low-carbon products, help to increase the sales quantity of carbon emission reduction products and thus increase the profits of each member of the dual-channel supply chain and the entire system. Therefore, a manager of an enterprise should widely publicize the results of the enterprise's carbon emission reduction, establish a positive image of the enterprise and educate consumers to awaken their environmental awareness, so as to improve the sales quantity and profit of the enterprise's carbon emission reduction products. In addition, if customers are more sensitive to carbon emission reduction, they will not only be more receptive to carbon emission reduction products but also in turn urge enterprises to reduce carbon emissions, which will be more beneficial to the earth's ecology and environmental protection.

Business managers should attach importance to developing new technologies to reduce carbon emissions. Simply increasing the amount of money to purchase carbon emission reduction equipment will lead to a substantial increase in the price of carbon emission reduction products, which will eventually rise to a high price that many consumers cannot accept. Therefore, a successful business manager must plan as soon as possible to develop low-cost carbon reduction technologies and equipment.

To improve the sales and profitability of industry suppliers, we need to understand the weaknesses of each part of the supply chain to reduce different cost components and then implement better industry marketing strategies. According to the research in this paper, we find that the manufacturer and retailer in the dual-channel supply chain can not only reduce the risk of capital contraction of the manufacturer and improve the income of the retailer through carbon emission reduction investment cooperation. More importantly, we can publicize the supply chain's investment in carbon emission reduction and technology development through advertising, establish a good image of the enterprise and build an environmental protection brand with sustainability and leading carbon reduction technology. Then, we can actively win the support or rewards of the government departments through the established good image. The operation of the customer group is not limited to the general customers with green environmental awareness; we can improve customers' sensitivity to carbon emission reduction through environmental education and publicity, awaken their environmental awareness and actively cultivate them to become a broader customer base.

Finally, we put forward the reflection of the research in this paper. Although the quantum game is a very useful tool, it requires more mathematical knowledge reserves and a lot of mathematical calculation processes, which is not conducive to generalizing the research results to general business managers. Therefore, the follow-up research direction should be simplified mathematical tools or related theories.

Figures

Quantum game with n players

Figure 1

Quantum game with n players

Research model structure

Figure 2

Research model structure

Quantum structure of the model

Figure 3

Quantum structure of the model

Selling prices and profits vary with the quantum entanglement

Figure 4

Selling prices and profits vary with the quantum entanglement

Selling prices and profits vary with the consumer's sensitivity

Figure 5

Selling prices and profits vary with the consumer's sensitivity

Selling prices and profits vary with the total emission reduction

Figure 6

Selling prices and profits vary with the total emission reduction

Selling prices and profit vary with β under centralized decision-making

Figure 7

Selling prices and profit vary with β under centralized decision-making

Centralized decision-making's selling prices and profit varying with θ

Figure 8

Centralized decision-making's selling prices and profit varying with θ

Overall supply chain’s profit varies with θ and β

Figure 9

Overall supply chain’s profit varies with θ and β

Profit comparison between two decision-making

Figure 10

Profit comparison between two decision-making

Value of model variables in numerical analysis

SymbolDescriptionValue
a0Potential market size to Q01,500
a1Potential market size to Q11,000
b0Direct price elasticity coefficient for the retail channel1.6
b1Direct price elasticity coefficient for the online channel1.5
αChannel cross-elasticity coefficient0.5
cProduct cost200
ωWholesale price220
kDifficulty degree coefficient of reduction in carbon emissions0.8
mInvestment ratio0.3
nProportion of the profit as the reward0.05
λCarbon tax rate0.2
CeOriginal carbon emission during product-making process5,000

Influence of quantum entanglement

Quantum entanglement γ00.11510
Retailer price p0d*890.13902.47997.001,037.521,037.54
Online price p1d*785.02795.92881.17918.69918.71
Retailer's profit π0d*603,823607,295622,772623,450623,449
Manufacturer's profit π1d*240,170243,228258,995261,295261,295
Overall system profit πscd*843,993850,523881,768884,744884,774

Influence of the consumer's sensitivity to carbon emission reduction

Consumer's sensitivity β0.20.40.60.81
Retailer price p0d*821.90909.45997.001,084.561,172.11
Online price p1d*695.03788.10881.17974.251,067.32
Retailer's profit π0d*325,305464,573622,772799,903995,964
Manufacturer's profit π1d*10,798.5125,347258,995411,473583,590
Overall system profit πscd*336,103589,920881,7681,211,6461,579,554

Influence of the total emission reduction

Carbon emission reduction θ2004006008001,000
Retailer price p0d*786.88839.41891.94944.47997.00
Online price p1d*657.80713.64769.49825.33881.17
Retailer's profit π0d*390,096452,442512,004568,780622,772
Manufacturer's profit π1d*238,969267,262280,031277,275258,995
Overall system profit πscd*629,065719,704792,034846,056881,768

Influence of β under centralized decision-making

Consumer's sensitivity β0.20.40.60.81
Retailer price p0c832.558925.581,018.601,111.631,204.65
Online price p1c744.186841.86939.541,037.211,134.88
Overall system profit πscc339,386593,805886,363121,706158,590

Influence of θ under centralized decision-making

Carbon emission reduction θ2004006008001,000
Retailer price p0c795.35851.16906.98962.791,018.60
Online price p1c705.12763.72822.33880.93939.54
Supply chain’s profit πscc632,138723,099795,790850,211886,363

Appendix 1. The Proof of Theorem 1

Proof. Substitute equations (37)–(40) into equations (22) and (23), we can get the profit functions of the retailer and manufacturer, respectively. According to the first derivative condition of the profit functions πjxj=0, j = 0, 1, the following are obtained:

[A11A12A21A22][x0x1]=[(L1nmL2)coshγ(mnL3ωα)sinhγL2sinhγL3coshγ],
where:

A11 = −2[b0 cosh2 γα(1 + nm)cosh γ sinh γ + nmb0 sinh2 γ];

A12 = a(1 + nm)cosh2 γ – 2(b0 + nmb1)cos γ sinh γ + a(1 + nm) sinh2γ;

A21 = αcosh2 γ − 2b1 coshγ sinhγ + α sinh2γ;

A22 = −2b1 cosh2 γ + 2α cosh γ sinh γ;

L1 = a0 + βθ + b0ω;

L2 = b0 (ωc) + ; and

L3 = a1 + βθ + b1c + α(ωc).

The second derivative condition of the profit functions are:

2π0x02=2[b0cosh2γα(1+nm)coshγsinhγ+nmb0sinh2γ],2π1x12=2b1cosh2γ+2αcoshγsinhγ.

By using sinh γ = (eγeγ)/2, cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2 and bj > 1 > n, m, α, j = 0, 1, we can get:

2π0x02=12{e2γ[(1+nm)(b0α)]+e2γ[(1nm)b0+(1+nm)α]+2(1nm)b0}<02π1x12=12{e2γ(b1+α)+e2γ(b1α)+2b1}<0.

Hence, this model has the optimal strategies. From the first derivative condition, by using cosh2 γ − sinh2 γ = 1, sinh γ = (eγeγ)/2, cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2 and bj > 1 > n, m, α, j = 0, 1, the determinant:

|A|=|A11A12A21A22|=4b0b1cosh2γ2α(b0+b1)coshγsinhγ(1+nm)α2,=14{[4b0b12α(b0+b1)](e2γ+e2γ)+2b0b1(1+nm)α2}>0.

By Cramer’s rule, the optimal strategies are:

x0=1|A|{cosh3γ[2b1(L1mnL2)+α(1+mn)L3]cosh2γsinhγ[α(2L1+(1mn)L2+2ωb1)+2b0L3]+coshγsinh2γ[2(b0+mnb1)L2+α(1mn)L3+2ωα2]sinh3γ[α(1+mn)L2]},
x1=1|A|{cosh3γ[α(L1mnL2ωα)+2b0L3]cosh2γsinhγ[α((2+mn)L3+ωα)+2(b1L1+(b0mnb1)L2)]+coshγsinh2γ[α(L1+(2+mn)L2+2ωb1)]sinh3γ[mn(αL32b1L2)]}.

Substitute the optimal strategies x0 and x1 into equations (37) and (38), then the optimal prices p0d* and p1d* can be obtained as follows:

p0d*=1|A|{cosh2γ[2b1(L1mnL2)+α(1+mn)L3]− coshγ sinhγ [α(L1+L2+2ωb1)]+sinh2γ [mn(2b1L2αL3)+ωα2]},
p1d*=1|A|{cosh2γ[α(L1mnL2)+2b0L3]coshγsinhγ[2b0L2+αL3+ωα2]+sinh2γ[α(1+mn)L2].

Appendix 2. The Proof of Theorem 2

Proof. Substitute equations (37)–(40) into equation (24), then we can get the overall supply chain’s profit function. The second-order partial derivatives of x0 and x1 for the profit function πsc are:

2πscx02=2[b0 cosh2γ2α coshγ sinh ⁡γ+b1 sinh2 γ],2πscx0x1=2πscx1x0=2[α cosh2 γ(b0+b1)cosh γ sinh γ+α sinh2 γ],2πscx12=2[b1 cosh2 γ2α coshγ sinh γ+b0 sinh2γ].

The determinant of the Hessian matrix:

|H(πsc)|=4(b0b1α2)(cosh2γsinh2γ)2=4(b0b1α2)>0.

By using sinh γ = (eγ – eγ)/2 and cosh γ = (eγ + eγ)/2, we can get:

2πscx02=12[e2γ(b0+b12α)+e2γ(b0+b1+2α)+2(b0b1)],
2πscx12=12[e2γ(b0+b12α)+e2γ(b0+b1+2α)+2(b1b0)].

Because γ = 0, we have 2πscx02=2b0<0 and 2πscx12=2b1<0. Hence, the Hessian matrix is negative definite. Then the optimal prices p0c and p1c exist.

According to the first derivative condition of the profit functions πscxj=0, j = 0, 1, the following are obtained:

[A¯11A¯12A¯21A¯22][x0x1]=[V0coshγV1sinhγV0sinhγV1coshγ],
where:
A¯11=2[b0 cosh2γ2α coshγ sinhγ+b1 sinh2γ];
A¯12=A¯21=2[α cosh2γ(b0+b1)coshγ sinhγ+α sinh2γ];
A¯22=2[b1 cosh2γ2α coshγ sinhγ+b0 sinh2γ];

V0 = a0 + βθ + b0cαc = L1L2; and

V1 = a1 + βθ + b1c − αc = L3αω.

Because the determinant:

|A¯|=|A¯11A¯12A¯21A¯22|=4(b0b1α2)(cosh2γsinh2γ)2=4(b0b1α2)>0,

by Cramer’s rule, the optimal strategies are:

x0=2[(sinhγαcoshγb1)V0+(coshγα+sinhγb0)V1]|A¯|=2b1V0+αV1|A¯|,x1=2[(coshγα+sinhγb1)V0+(sinhγαcoshγb0)V1]|A¯|=αV0+2b0V1|A¯|.

Substitute the optimal strategies x0 and x1 into equations (37) and (38), then the optimal prices p0c and p1c can be obtained as follows:

p0c*=2(b1V0+αV1)|A¯|=2[b1(L1L2)+α(L3αω)]|A¯|,
p1c*=2(αV0+b0V1)|A¯|=2[α(L1L2)+b0(L3αω)]|A¯|.

This completes the proof.

References

Adetutu, M.O., Odusanya, K.A. and Weyman-Jones, T.G. (2020), “Carbon tax and energy intensity: assessing the channels of impact using UK microdata”, The Energy Journal, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 143-166, doi: 10.5547/01956574.41.2.made.

Arrow, K.J. and Michael, D. (1981), Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 1, North-Holland.

Banker, R.D., Khosla, I. and Sinha, K.K. (1998), “Quality and competition”, Management Science, Vol. 44 No. 9, pp. 1179-1192, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.44.9.1179.

Cao, K., Xu, B., He, Y. and Xu, Q. (2020), “Optimal carbon reduction level and ordering quantity under financial constraints”, International Transactions in Operational Research, Vol. 27 No. 5, pp. 2270-2293, doi: 10.1111/itor.12606.

Chakravarty, S., Chikkatur, A., De Coninck, H., Pacala, S., Socolow, R. and Tavoni, M. (2009), “Sharing global CO2 emission reductions among one billion high emitters”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 106 No. 29, pp. 11884-11888, doi: 10.1073/pnas.0905232106.

Chiang, W.Y.K., Chhajed, D. and Hess, J.D. (2003), “Direct marketing, indirect profits: a strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design”, Management Science, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 1-20, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.49.1.1.12749.

Debreu, G. (1952), “A social equilibrium existence theorem”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 38 No. 10, pp. 886-893, doi: 10.1073/pnas.38.10.886.

Eisert, J., Wilkens, M. and Lewenstein, M. (1999), “Quantum games and quantum strategies”, Physical Review Letters, Vol. 83 No. 15, pp. 3077-3080, doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.83.3077.

Ellram, L.A. and Murfield, M.L.U. (2019), “Supply chain management in industrial marketing-relationships matter”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 79, pp. 36-45, doi: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2019.03.007.

Fan, K. (1952), “Fixed-point and minimax theorems in locally convex topological linear spaces”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 38 No. 2, pp. 121-126, doi: 10.1073/pnas.38.2.121.

Feng, W., Ji, G. and Pardalos, P.M. (2017), “Effects of government regulations on manufacturer's behaviors under carbon emission reduction”, Environmental Science and Pollution Research, Vol. 26 No. 18, pp. 17918-17926, doi: 10.1007/s11356-017-0891-4.

Flitney, A.P. and Hollenberg, L.C.L. (2007), “Nash equilibria in quantum games with generalized two-parameter strategies”, Physics Letters A, Vol. 363 Nos 5/6, pp. 381-388, doi: 10.1016/j.physleta.2006.11.044.

Fredriksson, P.G. and Millimet, D.L. (2002), “Strategic interaction and the determination of environmental policy across U.S. states”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 51 No. 1, pp. 101-122, doi: 10.1006/juec.2001.2239.

Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1991), Game Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, London, England.

Glicksberg, I.L. (1952), “A further generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem, with application to Nash equilibrium points”, Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, Vol. 3 No. 1, pp. 170-174, doi: 10.2307/2032478.

Golgeci, I. and Gligor, D.M. (2017), “The interplay between key marketing and supply chain management capabilities: the role of integrative mechanisms”, Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, Vol. 32 No. 3, pp. 472-483, doi: 10.1108/JBIM-05-2016-0102.

Holling, C.S. (1973), “Resilience and stability of ecological systems”, Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 1-23, doi: 10.12987/9780300188479-023.

Hong, G., Zhang, J. and Koehler, G.J. (2008), “A survey of quantum games”, Decision Support Systems, Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 318-332, doi: 10.1016/j.dss.2008.07.001.

Hua, G., Wang, S. and Cheng, T.E. (2010), “Price and lead time decisions in dual-channel supply chains”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 205 No. 1, pp. 113-126, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2009.12.012.

Huang, W. and Swaminathan, J.M. (2009), “Introduction of a second channel: implications for pricing and profits”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 194 No. 1, pp. 258-279, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2007.11.041.

Ichiishi, T. and Idzik, A. (1990), “Theorems on closed coverings of a simplex and their applications to cooperative game theory”, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, Vol. 146 No. 1, pp. 259-270, doi: 10.1016/0022-247X(90)90346-H.

, Q.D., Chew, Y.H. and Soong, B.H. (2016), Potential Game Theory, Springer International Publishing, doi: 10.1007/978-3-319-30869-2_1.

Lee, C.F., Lin, S.J. and Lewis, C. (2008), “Analysis of the impacts of combining carbon taxation and emission trading on different industry sectors”, Energy Policy, Vol. 36 No. 2, pp. 722-729, doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2007.10.025.

Lei, Y., Ji, J., Wang, M. and Wang, Z. (2018), “The manufacturer's joint decisions of channel selections and carbon emission reductions under the cap-and-trade regulation”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 193, pp. 506-523, doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.05.038.

Li, H., Du, J. and Massar, S. (2002), “Continuous-variable quantum games”, Physics Letters A, Vol. 306 Nos 2/3, pp. 73-78, doi: 10.1016/S0375-9601(02)01628-6.

Liang, Q.M., Fan, Y. and Wei, Y.M. (2007), “Carbon taxation policy in China: how to protect energy- and trade-intensive sectors?”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 29 No. 2, pp. 311-333, doi: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2006.11.001.

Liu, X. and Xu, H. (2022), “Does low-carbon pilot city policy induce low-carbon choices in residents' living: holistic and single dual perspective”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 324, p. 116353, doi: 10.1016/J.JENVMAN.2022.116353.

Liu, Z., Hu, B., Huang, B. and Lang, L. (2020), “Decision optimization of low-carbon dual-channel supply chain of auto parts based on smart city architecture”, Complexity, Vol. 2020 No. 5, pp. 1-14, doi: 10.1155/2020/2145951.

Liu, Z., Lang, L., Hu, B., Shi, L. and Zhao, Y. (2021), “Emission reduction decision of agricultural supply chain considering carbon tax and investment cooperation”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 294 No. 12, p. 126305, doi: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126305.

Marron, D.B. and Toder, E.J. (2014), “Tax policy issues in designing a carbon tax”, American Economic Review, Vol. 104 No. 5, pp. 563-68, doi: 10.1257/aer.104.5.563.

Meyer, D.A. (1999), “Quantum strategies”, Physical Review Letters, Vol. 82 No. 5, pp. 1052-1055, doi: 10.1103/PhysRevLett.82.1052.

Modak, N.M. and Kelle, P. (2019), “Managing a dual-channel supply chain under price and delivery-time dependent stochastic demand”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 272 No. 1, pp. 147-161, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.05.067.

Mukhopadhyay, S.K., Yue, X. and Zhu, X. (2011), “A Stackelberg model of pricing of complementary goods under information asymmetry”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 134 No. 2, pp. 424-433, doi: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2009.11.015.

Murray, B. and Rivers, N. (2015), “British Columbia’s revenue-neutral carbon tax: a review of the latest ‘grand experiment’ in environmental policy”, Energy Policy, Vol. 86, pp. 674-683, doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2015.08.011.

Nariê, R.D., de, S., Junqueira, T.L. and Otávio, C. (2021), “Opportunities and challenges for bioenergy-livestock integrated systems in Brazil”, Industrial Crops and Products, Vol. 173, doi: 10.1016/j.indcrop.2021.114091.

Nash, J.F. (1950), “Equilibrium points in n-person games”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 36 No. 1, pp. 48-49, doi: 10.1073/pnas.36.1.48.

Qiu, S., Wang, Z. and Liu, S. (2021), “The policy outcomes of low-carbon city construction on urban green development: evidence from a quasi-natural experiment conducted in China”, Sustainable Cities and Society, Vol. 66, p. 102699, doi: 10.1016/j.scs.2020.102699.

Sampford, C. (2009), “Re-conceiving the good life - the key to sustainable globalization”, Australian Journal of Social Issues, Vol. 45 No. 1, pp. 13-24, doi: 10.1002/j.1839-4655.2010.tb00160.x.

Sharma, A. and Jain, D. (2020), “A game theoretic analysis of dual-channel supply chain with Nash bargaining fairness concern”, Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, Vol. 35 No. 2, pp. 244-259, doi: 10.1108/JBIM-11-2018-0347.

Tan, H., Li, J., He, M., Li, J. and Zhang, C. (2021), “Global evolution of research on green energy and environmental technologies: a bibliometric study”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 297 No. 2, p. 113382, doi: 10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.113382.

Vives, X. (1990), “Nash equilibrium with strategic complementarities”, Journal of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 305-321, doi: 10.1016/0304-4068(90)90005-T.

Wang, M. and Feng, C. (2021), “Revealing the pattern and evolution of global green development between different income groups: a global meta-frontier by-production technology approach”, Environmental Impact Assessment Review, Vol. 89, p. 106600, doi: 10.1016/J.EIAR.2021.106600.

Yan, R. and Zhi, P. (2009), “Retail services and firm profit in a dual-channel market”, Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, Vol. 16 No. 4, pp. 306-314, doi: 10.1016/j.jretconser.2009.02.006.

Yao, D.Q. and Liu, J.J. (2005), “Competitive pricing of mixed retail and E-tail distribution channels”, Omega, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 235-247, doi: 10.1016/j.omega.2004.04.007.

Zhao, Y.H. (2011), “The study of effect of carbon tax on the international competitiveness of energy-intensive industries: an empirical analysis of OECD 21 countries, 1992-2008”, Energy Procedia, Vol. 5 No. 5, pp. 1291-1302, doi: 10.1016/j.egypro.2011.03.225.

Zhi, B., Liu, X., Chen, J. and Jia, F. (2019), “Collaborative carbon emission reduction in supply chains: an evolutionary game-theoretic study”, Management Decision, Vol. 57 No. 4, pp. 1087-1107, doi: 10.1108/MD-09-2018-1061.

Zhou, J., Ma, L. and Li, Y. (2005), “Multiplayer quantum games with continuous-variable strategies”, Physics Letters A, Vol. 339 Nos 1/2, pp. 10-17, doi: 10.1016/j.physleta.2005.03.006.

Acknowledgements

The research was supported by the Startup Research Fund of Xiamen University Tan Kah Kee College, JG2018SRF10.

Corresponding author

Yu-Chung Chang can be contacted at: 2933662796@qq.com

Related articles